Money and society in pre-Roman Britain
Barry Cunliffe
Nearly 40 years ago, in April 1940, Derek Allen presented
his now-classic paper ‘The Belgic dynasties of Britain and
their Coins’ before a meeting of the Society of Antiquaries
in London (Allen 1944). In it he set out to construct a
history of the late pre-Roman Iron Age of Britain, based on
a geographical, stylistic, and chronological study of the
surviving coinage. This work, with periodic updatings, has
remained a standard part of subsequent considerations of
the British Iron Age. The CBA Conference on the Problems
of the Iron Age in Southern Britain, held in London in
1958, provided Allen with the opportunity to reappraise the
origins of coinage in Britain (Allen 1961). His considered
views, stated with great clarity, were readily accepted by
subsequent writers (Frere 1967; Hawkes 1968; Cunliffe
1974), all of whom found that his historical approach
provided a satisfactory model against which to consider the
rest of the archaeological evidence. One should, however,
call to mind Allen’s perceptive warning: ‘It is essential in
interpreting coin evidence to recall constantly that it is only
Part, and not always the most important part, of the
historical record’ (Allen 1961, 98).
The historical approach to coinage has continued to
develop. Rodwell’s detailed restudy of the coinage of south-
eastern Britain extends and refines the arguments, pre-
senting a meticulously argued ‘history’ for the period
based substantially on changes in coin type and distribution
(Rodwell 1976), while the work of Simone Scheers in
France and the Low Countries uses historical events as a
framework for understanding the coinage (Scheers 1972;
1977). The historical model is further examined in the
recent work of John Kent (Kent 1978a and below, pp
4 0 - 2 ) .
Whilst the historical approach thus continues to thrive,
the vogue for discovering and analysing economic systems
in archaeology, which developed in the 1960s, led some
writers to focus attention on the potential of the coin
evidence in studies of this kind (Collis 1971a; 1971 b; 1974;
Haselgrove 1976). The writer, by virtue of his early
archaeological training, must confess to being more in
sympathy with this school of thought. The present paper,
however, is an attempt to consider the quality of the data
against the broad social questions which might reasonably
be asked of it, rather than to engage in the polemic which
surrounds model building whether historical or economic.
The nature of the evidence
Before we can begin we must briefly consider the nature of
the available data. In all some 12 624 Iron Age coins are
recorded from Britain. Probably less than 50% survive
today. Of this impressive total c 3 100 come from the single
‘hoard’ found at Hengistbury and a further 5 200+ from
other hoards. A mere 1 l00+ have been found in excavations
(the majority come from three sites: Camulodunum,
Braughing, and Harlow), and of these a substantial
proportion are unstratified. Furthermore, it is estimated
that of the 5 000 or so coins recorded on the Index housed in
the Institute of Archaeology, Oxford, about two-thirds are
without precise provenance.
Thus it must be realized at the outset that the data have
widely varying levels of reliability. To a numismatist dealing
with metrology, typology, die linking, etc, the data are of
reasonable quality but to an archaeologist working with
distribution patterns they are far from adequate. Not only is
29
most of the sample unusable because of lack of locational
detail, it is also regionally biased by the many factors
affecting discovery, and worse still, it is distorted to an
unknown extent by the unscrupulous who wish to please
collectors (including museums) by providing false find spots
for material which is either without a sound location or was
acquired and dispersed under dubious circumstances
(Rodwell, below, pp 43-52). While distribution maps can
quite reasonably be used in generalizing arguments, to
attempt to use them too precisely to generate sophisticated
models can give rise only to a spurious and misleading
impression of accuracy.
Where individual site finds are concerned we are in even
more difficulty. It is only in recent excavations like those at
the temples of Harlow and Hayling or the urban sites of
Braughing, Colchester, and Canterbury that reliable data
are at last being provided. The distorting effects which
these collections have on our maps is a firm reminder of the
inadequacy of much of the rest of the record. This is not
intended to be a counsel of despair but a warning that we
should not ask of the data questions which, in full
knowledge of their limitations, they cannot be expected
reliably to answer. In the following pages we will therefore
use the evidence of the coinage at a general, rather than too
specific, a level.
Britain and the Continent, c 120-40 BC
Most scholars will agree that coinage was introduced into
Britain during the period 120-50 BC, but the economic and
social situation in the south-east of the country, and in
particular the differences in the different regional systems,
are seldom taken into account. Some aspects of these
problems have been dealt with recently elsewhere (Cunliffe
1976; 1978a) but several points deserve mention here.
Foremost is the fact that in the early part of the period the
south-east of Britain can be divided into two distinct
regions: a hillfort-dominated zone stretching from Kent and
Sussex westwards to Wessex and the Cotswolds, and an
area of open settlement occupying the Thames Valley, East
Anglia, and the Midlands. This same division is emphasized
by a consideration of the ceramics of the area. Clearly, two
separate socio-economic systems are implied. In both zones
coinage was adopted and a full-scale market economy
eventually developed.
To suggest however that the idea of coinage in its various
manifestations was completely novel might prove to be
misleading. Widespread use of currency bars appears on
present evidence to have preceded the introduction of
coinage (if overlapping with it), while the discovery at
several sites (including Winklebury and Danebury) of well
made stone weights implies that careful measurement was
being practised. It may well be that salt packed in ceramic
containers formed another unit of value (Cunliffe 1977;
214), while the possibility that storage pits for grain may
have been dug to a series of size standards is a further
reminder that accurate measurement, in the interests of
exchange, may have been widespread. To this we might
perhaps add that some at least of the large numbers of
Greek coins found in south-eastern Britain are likely to be
genuine Iron Age imports, thus familiarizing the natives
with the idea of the coin as a unit of value. In other words,
at the time when large-scale long-distance trade was
re-established in the first half of the 1st century BC, it is
30
Cunliffe: Money and society in pre-Roman Britain
Fig 11 Britain and the Continent showing the most convenient points of contact:
ports of trade,
Armorican coins,
Gallo-Belgic coins
reasonable to assume that the communities of the south-east
already practised an ordered economy in which measure-
ment by weight and possibly by volume formed an essential
part. In such circumstances the ready adoption of coinage
need occasion no surprise nor would it be exceptional if a
money economy were to develop soon after.
Pre-Caesarian contact
Two principal axes of contact between Britain and the
Continent seem to have developed in the decades before
Caesar’s invasions in 55 and 54 BC. Not surprisingly, the
routes chosen spanned the shortest sea crossings, requiring
the traveller to spend a minimum of time our of easy reach
of land (Fig 11), One axis linked the western seaways, via
Armorica, to central southern Britain, and the other lay
between northern France and the Low Countries (Belgica)
and the Thames estuary.
Evidence for the western axis, between Armorica and
Hengistbury Head, has recently been discussed by the
writer in some detail (Cunliffe 1978b) and need not detain
us here. Suffice it to say that there is ample archaeological
evidence for widespread trade involving the importation of
pottery from Armorica and wine from Italy in exchange for
which metals are the most evident of the possible British
e x p o r t s . A p a r t f r o m t h e e s t a b l i s h m e n t o f w h a t c a n
Cunliffe: Money and society in pre-Roman Britain
31
Fig 12 Distribution of Gallo-Belgic B and Potin 1 coins mapped after Allen 1961 and Haselgrove I978
reasonably be regarded as a port-of-trade at Hengistbury
and a general improvement in pottery technology in the
south-west of Britain (probably involving the introduction
of the potter’s wheel), the trading axis had little lasting
effect on the socio-economic structure of the Iron Age
communities of southern Britain.
From the point of view of the present discussion it is the
numismatic aspect of the contact that is of interest. It is
represented by 60 or so imported Armorican coins scattered
over central southern England of which 25 come from
Hengistbury, a distribution sufficient in itself to imply some
form of contact even if no other evidence had been
available. That the subsequent local coinages owe little,
apart from adherence to a silver standard, to imported
Armorican types, but instead develop from Gallo-Belgic
models introduced from eastern Britain, strongly suggests
that Armorican coins in Britain represented little more than
valued items of precious metal: they do not seem to reflect
the introduction of a new trading system based on money
economy. The fact that the socio-economic system, as
exemplified by the continued development of hillforts,
appears to remain unchanged is a further indication that
trade with Armorica had little lasting effect on southern
Britain. The reasons for this are obscure. The contact could
have been (and indeed probably was) short-lived, but of
equal importance may have been the fact that the economic
and social systems in the area were not, at this time,
sufficiently structured to allow the easy adoption of the new
32
Cunliffe: Money and society in pre-Roman Britain
Fig 13 Distribution of Gallo-Belgic A-F coins (after Allen 1961 and Huselgrove 1978)
exchange system. The Armorican contact seems, then, to
provide an interesting example of one of the many kinds of
relationship, involving the transference of coins, which may
have existed between communities.
The relationship
between the Belgic territories and
eastern Britain was quite different but in view of the
current discussions concerning the chronology of the Gallo-
Belgic coin series (Kent 1978a) it is unwise to argue the
sequence of events too closely. Most writers are agreed,
however, that Gallo-Belgic B coins were probably in use in
Britain in the decades before Caesar’s conquest, and some
of the Gallo-Belgic A examples may well have been in
circulation in this period. The distribution of Gallo-Belgic B
centres upon the Thames estuary favouring Kent, a distri-
bution pattern very similar to that of the Potin I coinage for
which Allen has argued a pre-conquest date. Mapped
together (Fig 12) the gross distribution of Gallo-Belgic B
and Potin I probably reflects the territory within which
coinage first came into regular use in Britain. The Potin
coinage is of particular interest for not only was it minted in
Britain but its very existence must surely imply a system of
currency involving two denominations. Collis has found it
difficult to accept that potin represents small change in a
money economy (Collis 1974), but Rodwell has countered
his arguments (1976, 207-8). While the matter is still open
to debate, particularly in view of the uncertainty of the
dating evidence, we can tentatively suggest that the earliest
development of British coinage took place in Kent and that