Phase of the Business Cycle and Portfolio Management
David Nawrocki
Professor of Finance
Department of Finance
College of Commerce and Finance
Villanova, PA 19085 USA
610-489-7520 Voice and Fax
610-519-4323 Office and Voice Mail
610-489-0750 Home
David.Nawrocki@Villanova.Edu
NawrockiD@aol.com
William Carter
The QInsight Group
San Diego, CA
619-295-9292 Office
wcarter@qinsight.com
Preliminary: Do not quote without permission of the authors.
The QInsight Group assumes no responsibility for the views or opinions expressed in this paper.
The authors bear full responsibility for the views and opinions expressed in this paper. The
performance results are provided as part of an academic study and are not to be construed as
expectations of future performance.
March 1997
2
Phase of the Business Cycle and Portfolio Management
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to explore the business cycle and to see whether it influences portfolio
performance. Hunt[1976] provides the econometric work that serves as the basis for determining the
phase of the cycle. The study uses the Standard & Poors industry indexes, individual security data and
macroeconomic data to study the business cycle. The tests include a portfolio strategy that switches
between industries based on the phase of the economy. The paper concludes that the business cycle
influences the performance of stock portfolios and that the phases of the business cycle relate to the phases
in Vaga's[1990] Coherent Market Hypothesis.
Introduction
The relationship between economic activity and cyclical behavior in the money and capital markets has
not received a great deal of attention in the finance literature. Arnott and Copeland[1985] demonstrate
that the business cycle has a significant effect on security returns. Chen, Roll and Ross[1986] determine
that certain macroeconomic variables (industrial production, changes in the yield curve, and expected
inflation) are significant indicators of changes in stock returns. In addition, Moore[1983] explores the
relationship between inflation and business cycles.
Recently, Peters[1991,1994] using rescaled range (R/S) analysis finds evidence of long term
nonperiodic cycles in stock returns that average approximately 48 months in duration. Nawrocki[1995]
confirms this result but finds that the cycle is dependent on changes in the money supply and industrial
production.
Other academic studies focus on the effect that the economic cycle has on the microstructure of the
market, (e.g., Abraham and Ikenberry[1994], Liano[1992], Liano and Gup[1989], and Liano, Huang and
Gup[1993]). Recently, Bauman and Miller[1995] find that the ranking of investment performance is
more consistent over time with complete stock market cycles evaluations rather than market cycle subset
evaluations. Bauman and Miller differ from other studies in that they study the peak to peak stock market
cycle rather than the peak to peak business cycle as measured by industrial production. Stovall(1996)
takes an additional step and breaks the business cycle into five phases. Using the S&P Industry Indexes,
3
he is able to demonstrate that different industries dominate (in terms of total return) during each phase.
Stovall concludes that an industry sector rotation strategy based on the business cycle will improve
investment performance.
The major questions to be answered are: Is knowledge of the business cycle necessary in order to
manage investment portfolios? Does the stock market rotate into and out of industries in response to
changes in the business cycle?
The concept of a business cycle is interesting. One position is that it is generated by a time-varying
parameter model. As parameters (technology, preferences, rate of financial innovation) of the model
change it can experience different states of nature. The changing parameters represent “surprise” to the
system which must adapt to the parameters. (The formal definition of information arrival in Shannon and
Weaver’s, 1947, information theory is for a message to have information content it must represent
“surprise” to the receiver of the message.) If the business cycle can be forecasted, there would be no
business cycle. Economic agents anticipating the forecasted parameter changes will make appropriate
adjustments to minimize the impact of the changes, hence, no cycle. This view of the economy as
constantly evolving over time through different states of nature with time-varying parameters is described
in Nawrocki(1984), Anderson, Arrow and Pines(1988) and Vaga(1990, 1994).
Vaga[1990,1994], in particular, takes an interesting approach describing the stock market as moving
through different types of market behavior. Vaga's market phases include random walk markets,
transition markets, coherent markets and chaotic markets. Vaga identifies the statistical properties of
each market type. One perspective of this paper is whether Vaga’s market phases relate to the business
cycle.
Even with this interest in the area of business cycles, Hunt[1976] is the only study that stresses the
econometric relationship between macroeconomic variables to detect transition points where the business
cycle transitions to new states of nature. Hunt studies macrovariables such as the federal funds rates,
capital market yields, business credit demands, unemployment claims, non-farm payroll, inflation, and
monetary and reserve aggregates. The relationships between these variables help determine the different
phases of the economic cycle. The purpose of Hunt’s work is to identify the change in the business cycle,
4
not to forecast it. The first priority of this paper is to see whether Hunt’s methodology is replicable to
identify different phases in the economic cycle.
Identifying the phases of the economy allows the determination of which industries perform best
during individual phases. Therefore, a portfolio strategy that switches between industries will be
backtested to see whether the phase information is useful in the construction of portfolios. This paper
differs from previous work since it breaks the business cycle into its component phases and uses an
industry rotation strategy to take advantage of the individual phases of an economic cycle. Specifically,
the study utilizes the 1970-1986 period to identify the phases of the economy and the resulting industry
performance. A performance test of the industry rotation strategy then utilizes the 1988-1995 period.
(The year 1987 is not in the study since the market crash of 1987 results in highly skewed, leptokurtic
distributions for that period. It is realistic that an investment manager in March 1988 would make the
same decision after looking at the distributions with and without 1987.) The structure of the study
provides a holdout (out of sample) period and avoids the “look ahead” bias that is possible with empirical
backtests of investment strategies. The “look ahead” bias includes the problems of “data mining” or “data
snooping”.
The next section of the paper addresses the methodology used in the study, while the discussion of the
empirical results follows. The final section presents the conclusions of the paper.
Methodology
The portfolio strategy consists of the following steps:
•
Statistical Analysis to Determine Phases of the Business Cycle.
•
The Determination of the Best Industry Performance for each Phase of the Cycle.
•
Portfolio Selection Algorithm to Select 20 Asset Portfolio for Each Phase of the Cycle.
The Data
The data include monthly percentage return data for the S&P 500 Composite index as well as for over
100 S&P Industry indexes obtained from Standard & Poors. The data also includes macroeconomic
variables from the Citibase/Fame/DRI database. This data is available for the period starting
5
in January 1970 and ending in June 1994. The test of the industry rotation model uses weekly relative
return data for 1510 stocks for the period March 1988 to February 1995. A screening procedure results in
the sample of 1510 stocks. In order to control liquidity costs, stocks with prices under $10 per share and
market capitalization under $250 million are not in the sample. To handle any additional implicit trading
costs, the transaction fee during portfolio revisions is 0.5% which is higher than the 0.2-0.3% available
through discount brokers to larger accounts (such as an investment manager or a mutual fund).
Statistical Analysis
The period from 1969 to 1994 is an interesting period. As demonstrated in Table 1, there were three
distinct phases in the US economy during this period. The first period is a period of increasing inflation
because of the Vietnam War and the failure of the US government to raise taxes to pay for the war. This
period is notable for increasing prices particularly fuel prices. To make matters worse, stocks and bonds
exhibit very low or negative returns, thus providing negative changes in purchasing power when investing
in financial assets. A tangible asset, gold, is the biggest gainer. However, an investor should note that the
US drops the gold standard on international payments during this period and allows gold to float with the
market prices. The next period is easy to pick because of the Arab-Israeli war in 1973 and the resulting
oil embargo. This is the period of the oil crisis with double digit increases in energy prices over the rest of
the decade. The stock market rebounds sharply during this period. However, on a real basis, it is only
recovering from the 1969-1973 decline. Gold maintains its high real rate of return. After the 1979 oil
crisis and the double dip recessions of 1980-82, the US economy entered into its current phase. Factors
important in selecting 1983 to start this period include the non-effect of the Iraq-Iran war on fuel prices
and the recovery of the US economy from the double-dip recessions. Inflation is below average and
approaches the inflation rates of the late 1950s and early 1960s. Inflation in fuel prices is nonexistent.
On a real basis, fuel prices decline since 1982. Stocks and bonds provide high real returns during this
period while tangible assets like gold lose purchasing power.
Place Table 1 Here
6
The Hunt(1976) methodology for determining phases of the economy studies the economic cycle for
structural changes. Table 2 provides the definitions of Hunt’s five phases of the economic cycle, and the
behavior of macroeconomic variables during these phases and the resulting decision rules used to
determine a phase change.
Place Table 2 Here
Table 3 presents the results of utilizing Hunt’s methodology for the period from 1970 to 1986. The
peaks and troughs are from the NBER’s Survey of Current Business. The NBER does not publish the
official peak and trough dates until well after the event. Therefore, an investment strategy cannot be
formulated using the NBER announcements. The macroeconomic variables have to be studied in order to
identify the phase of the business cycle at the time of the phase change. Hunt’s methodology consists of
following macroeconomic statistics that are relatively hard numbers. That is, they are not based on
sampling and are usually not subject to revision. Even if the variable is subsequently revised, only the
originally announced value is included in this study. The variables consist of money supply, interest rates,
and unemployment claims. Sample variables consist of inflation, non-farm payroll, and industrial
production. These variables are published on a monthly basis and are rarely revised. Hunt uses
econometric relationships, correlations, reversals in variables, and time series analysis to determine when
a change in phase has taken place. (It is not possible to describe Hunt’s methodology in a short research
paper. Hunt(1976) requires an entire book to develop and explain the methodology.) The method is
adaptive, not a proactive forecasting technique. Vaga(1990) also provides statistical tools such as
skewness, kurtosis and serial correlations to determine market phases.
The easeoff and plunge phases are consistent with the peaks and troughs from the Survey through
1982. (The 11/82 trough is missed by one month.) The easeoff and plunge period noted in 1984 did not
meet the NBER’s definition but it did meet Hunt’s macroeconomic conditions. (In addition, the
appropriate industry rotation did occur in the stock market.) This is a strong confirmation of Hunt’s
methodology since the NBER defined peaks and troughs are not known until months after his
methodology indicates the phase change. Knowing the actual dates of the peaks and troughs is not
necessary. It is sufficient to know the general phase in which the peak or trough takes place in order to
7
benefit from the sector rotation strategy. The economy reaches a peak during the Easeoff phase. At this
point the Federal Reserve is following a tight monetary policy that is characterized by large increases in
the federal funds rate and decreases in the monetary aggregates. Growth in non-farm payroll slows and
there is an increase in initial unemployment claims. Therefore, industrial production reaches a peak and
starts to fall. In the meantime, inflation peaks.
The economy reaches a trough during the Plunge phase. Industrial production declines as does non-
farm payroll. Initial unemployment claims continue to increase. The Federal Reserve, meanwhile, is
increasing monetary aggregates and decreasing the federal funds rate in an attempt to stimulate the
economy. Inflation slows to its lowest level during the economic cycle. The stock market exhibits very
high returns as it is anticipating the economic revival as a result of the Federal Reserve policy.
The early revival (Revival1) starts with large increases in industrial production and increasing federal
funds rates. The monetary aggregates continue to grow along with non-farm payroll. Initial
unemployment claims drop drastically. Inflation ticks up a bit. Again the stock market exhibits high
returns.
The transition to the late revival (Revival2) exhibits decreasing stock market returns, slower growth
in the monetary aggregates and moderating inflation. Generally, the economy is very stable during this
period with stable growth in industrial production and stable prices. The stock market returns while lower
are also very stable.
An increase in inflation and a restrictive Federal Reserve monetary policy mark the beginning of the
Accelerate phase. The federal funds rates increase rapidly, and the growth in the monetary aggregates
declines drastically. The overheating economy is evident by the largest gains during the cycle in nonfarm
payrolls and large drops in initial unemployment claims. Industrial production is still increasing at a high
rate, but is starting to slow because of the restrictive Federal Reserve policy. The stock market starts to
decline in anticipation of a future recession.
Table 3 also provides the econometric performance during these phases. During the Easeoff period,
there is a correlation between the federal funds rate, the monetary base, the employment numbers and
industrial production. These same variables along with inflation and the M1 money supply are significant
8
relative to industrial production during the Plunge phase. Note that information concerning the transition
to a new phase is not available until after the transition. Analysts have to watch for changing correlations
as well as changing macroeconomic variables.
The federal funds rate, the monetary base, employment numbers and inflation are the important
variables to watch during the transition to a Revival 1 phase. The important variables during the revival
2 phase are changes in monetary base, employment numbers and inflation. The federal funds rate is not a
factor. The only factor that is significant during the Accelerate phase is the non-farm payroll. The
sudden acceleration of the nonfarm payroll as well as slowing growth in the real monetary base signifies a
change in the stock market.
Each phase lasts for at least six months. This introduces the point that it is not necessary to forecast
the phase changes but rather to adapt to changes in economic conditions. There is time in each phase to
benefit from the economic conditions of the phase. The adaptation is necessary since most of the
macroeconomic data is not available to the markets until weeks after the change in economic conditions.
Place Table 3 Here
Vaga’s Stock Market Phases
Vaga(1990,1994) proposes that the stock market moves through distinctive phases over time. Vaga
describes the phases statistically. Table 4 summarizes Vaga’s four phases of the stock market. Vaga’s
descriptions derive from the return, risk, skewness and kurtosis of the stock market returns. As can be
seen in Table 4, investors do best in coherent markets and random walk markets. It is best to avoid
chaotic markets and transition markets. The statistical properties of the stock market during the different
phases of the economy are interesting given Vaga’s work. The random walk exhibits average returns and
average risk levels. As is common with random walk conditions, the best strategy is to buy and hold a
diversified portfolio. A coherent market by definition is easy to forecast. Diversified portfolios provide
high returns and low risk. In addition, investors may utilize forecasting techniques to increase returns.
The transition market occurs as the market moves from coherent to chaotic to random. It is a difficult
market period for investors depending on the transition. A chaotic market provides the unhappy
combination of low returns and high risk.
9
Place Table 4 Here
Industry Performance
Next, using monthly data from January 1970 to December 1986, the risk-return performance ranks the
S&P industry indexes for each of the five phases. (December 1986 was the end of a Revival 2 phase. The
next phase continued past the simulation starting point of March 1988.) A more sophisticated measure of
risk, the reward-to-lower partial moment (R/LPM) ratio, provides a ranking of the industry indexes.
Research conducted by Ang and Chua[1979], Nawrocki(1983), and Harlow[1991] support the use of LPM
in a portfolio allocation process because of its statistical superiority over the variance measure. For the
interested reader, Markowitz[1991, 374-376] provides a comprehensive bibliography of
semivariance/lower partial moment research. The n-degree lower partial moment is a measure of
downside risk where the semivariance is a special case (n=2). Fishburn(1977) provides the theoretical
arguments for using the n-degree lower partial moment. Table 5 lists the top 15 industries as ranked by
the R/LPM for each phase.
Place Table 5 Here
Portfolio Selection Algorithms
Operations research has a long history of using heuristic algorithms because of computational
complexity of optimal algorithms. Typically, the heuristic algorithm derives mathematically from the
optimal algorithm, thus providing replicable results. The advantage of the heuristic algorithm is usually
that it is simpler and less costly to implement. With modern microcomputers, this is not the important
factor of twenty-five years ago. Using historical data, an optimal quadratic code will provide a more
efficient portfolio set than a heuristic algorithm. However, portfolio management does not take place in
the past but rather in the future. Therefore, the question becomes which algorithm, heuristic or optimal,
provides the best portfolio management performance. Statistical tests by Elton, Gruber and Urich[1978]
and economic tests by Nawrocki[1990] demonstrate that heuristic algorithms provide better ex post
performance than optimal algorithms.
This study employs the R/LPM heuristic algorithm because of its historic performance and because it is
easy to implement with maximum allocation constraints. This simple heuristic algorithm derives from
10
Sharpe's[1967] idea that a heuristic algorithm can ignore intercorrelations between securities if the
number of securities in the portfolio is sufficiently large (20 or more). Sharpe proposes this algorithm in
order to handle maximum investment constraints necessary for mutual fund operations. The resulting
algorithm is as follows:
Z
i
= (R
i
-R
f
)/(LPM
n
), (1)
where R
i
is the return on security i, R
f
is the riskfree rate of return and LPM
n
is the n-degree lower
partial moment. The allocations represent a weighting according to the R/LPM ratio. The allocations
compute as follows:
k
X
i
= Z
i
/
Σ
Z
j
for all Z
j
> 0, (2)
j=1
where k is the number of securities where Z
i
> 0. The portfolio heuristic algorithm in this study uses
weekly security relative returns and treasury bill relative returns as the target return.
Selecting the parameters of the R/LPM portfolio algorithm is important in order to avoid “data
snooping” or “look ahead” bias. A random sample of 150 securities from the CRSP dataset for the period
1958 to 1987 provides a backtest. (The algorithm study ends in 1987 so that the industry rotation study
commencing in 1988 avoids the “look ahead” bias.) The R/LPM heuristic algorithm uses 3, 6, 12, 24, 36
and 48 month revision periods to test for the appropriate parameters. An optimal covariance algorithm
(Markowitz, 1991)and an optimal cosemivariance algorithm (Hogan & Warren, 1972) are also in the
study. A summary of the results is in Table 6. For all revision periods, the LPM heuristic algorithm
outperforms the optimal algorithms on a risk-return basis. In addition, the table reports the degree of the
LPM that achieves the maximum performance. This paper concerns itself with quarterly revision as the
economic data for each quarter becomes available. For three month revisions, a degree of 1.2 provides the
best performance for the LPM heuristic.
Place Table 6 Here
11
Availability of Economic Data for Determining Phases
Determining the phase of the economic cycle is a reactive (adaptive) process. There is a lag in the
time from when the economy changes phases to the time when the economic data indicates the change.
As a result, the investment strategy is an adaptive strategy rather than a proactive forecasting strategy.
Because of the time lag in obtaining economic data, investment decisions that result from this data will
not occur at the end of a calendar quarter. There is a lag until the information is available. Therefore,
quarterly revision decisions occur in the middle of February, May, August and November. This
investment strategy follows a Murphy(1965) Type II adaptive control process. A Type II process consists
of a decision vector which is dependent on an environmental vector (current state of nature) and a
historical information vector (previous states of nature). The decision is made with a one period lag since
the decision cannot be made without the arrival of the new information. This represents a more realistic
application of the investment strategy and improves the validity of the backtest.
Investment Strategies
The investment strategies employed in this study include:
•
S&P500 which is a buy and hold in the S&P 500 composite index during each quarter.
•
No Indust which is a 20 asset R/LPM heuristic algorithm portfolio (equations 1 and 2) selected from
the entire database of 1510 stocks. There is no implementation of industry selection by phase.
•
Industry which is a 20 asset R/LPM heuristic algorithm portfolio selected from the 1510 stocks
database except the stocks are screened by the appropriate industries for the current economic phase..
If the stock is a member of an appropriate industry for the current phase, then its inclusion into the
portfolio is determined by its R/LPM ratio (equations 1 and 2).
All investment strategies are buy-and-hold during the quarter without any implementation of stop loss or
other portfolio insurance schemes. Input statistics for the algorithm derive from a historic period of the
previous 104 weeks. Backtesting during the 1981-86 period indicates that the 104 week historic period
provides the best forecasting performance.
12
Empirical Results
Quarterly Performance Results
Table 7 presents the first set of out-of-sample results from 1988 to 1995. On an aggregate basis, the
R/LPM 20 asset portfolios with industry rotation outperform the S&P index over the seven year period
both in terms of return and risk-return. The S&P index does provide lower risk than the R/LPM portfolios
at the cost of reduced returns and risk-return performance. On an individual quarter basis, the R/LPM 20
asset portfolio outperforms the S&P 500 index during 20 of 28 quarters. This is statistically significant
using a binomial test of significance where p=0.5 is the null hypothesis (0.0188). The binomial test uses a
normal approximation with a mean, np, and the variance, np(1-p) to compute the appropriate
probabilities [Hastings and Peacock, 1975]. The normal approximation applies whenever n>20 and np>5
and n(1-p) >5.
The interesting results in Table 7 are the moving 104 week calculations of skewness, kurtosis, and the
one week lag serial correlations. During phases 2, 3, and 5 (plunge, early revival, accelerate), the 104
week serial correlations are significantly negative. There are insignificant serial correlations during
Phases 1 and 4. The skewness and kurtosis numbers are especially interesting. Phases 1, 2, and 5 exhibit
significantly negative skewness and are leptokurtic while phases 3 and 4 have insignificant skewness and
kurtosis values close to 3.0. The transition from Easeoff (1) to Plunge(2) is striking. The skewness and
kurtosis numbers drop drastically while the serial correlation suddenly becomes significantly negative.
The transition from Plunge(2) to Revival 1(3) occurs with skewness values turning insignificant. The
transition from Revival 1(3) to Revival 2(4) again is sudden with the serial correlations becoming
insignificant. A switch back to significant negative serial correlations marks the beginning of the
Accelerate(5) phase.
Phase 3, early revival, seems to be a transition period since it has significant negative serial correlation
while serial correlations in phase 4, late Revival, are insignificant. Phase 4 provides results close to a
random walk, i.e., insignificant serial correlation and distributions that are approximately normal. These
results correspond to Vaga's[1990] coherent market hypothesis. Note that in Table 4, leptokurtic
13
distributions with significant skewness characterize Vaga's coherent and chaotic markets, while the
random walk market is symmetric and mesokurtic (kurtosis = 3.0).
The correspondence between the phases determined by Hunt’s methodology and the statistics determining
Vaga’s market states is important. It indicates that the statistical stages of Vaga’s coherent market model
have an economic (business cycle) foundation.
Place Table 7 Here
Performance Results by Phase
To further explore this result, Table 8 presents the aggregate results for the trading strategies in the
five phases. The R/LPM portfolio selection employs both industry selection and no industry selection for
security screening. Overall, the industry rotation strategy performs better than the other investment
strategies (except for Phase 3 - Revival 1).
In phase 1, Easeoff, the industry selection using historic 104 week estimates provides the best
performance. Significant negative skewness, a high degree of kurtosis and significant serial correlation
characterize the first phase. Of the five phases, phase 1 provides the highest returns, which is consistent
with the high returns during the 1983-1994 period in Table 1. Phase 1 provides a different result during
the last economic cycle than it did during the 1970s and early 1980s with high positive returns during the
recent period and negative returns during the 1970-1986 period. While phase 1 does not exhibit the low
risk that Vaga identifies with a coherent market, it has the best risk-return performance of the five phases
and significant serial correlation. As such it meets the criteria of a Vaga coherent market.
Phase 2, Plunge, provides results consistent with a Vaga random walk market: symmetric
distributions, kurtosis values close to 3.0 and insignificant serial correlation. The risk-return performance
is less than the average for the total period. The industry selected portfolios again provide the best risk-
return performance.
A Vaga transition market period characterizes phase 3, Revival 1, because of the kurtosis value for the
S&P 500 index is 2.0 (platykurtic). The distributions are symmetric and there is very low serial
correlation. The R/LPM heuristic without industry selection provides the best risk-return performance.
14
The S&P return does not follow the past history exhibiting losses rather than the large gains available
during the 1970-1986 period.
Phase 4, Revival 2, is the coherent market period that Vaga speaks so highly about in his work since
it exhibits higher than average returns and lower than average risks. There is also the significantly
skewed and leptokurtic distributions identified by Vaga. The industry selection provides the best risk-
return performance.
Phase 5, Accelerate, is an appropriate time for a portfolio manager to take a vacation. It exhibits the
worst risk-return performance as well as the lowest overall returns. This is very interesting result since
Hunt(1987) discusses how his investment managers take Caribbean vacations during the Accelerate
phase. The distributions are slightly leptokurtic with some serial correlation. Again the industry
selection provides the best performance. The pattern of increasing risk and lower return fit Vaga's
description of a chaotic market period. All of the phases exhibit the statistical characteristics of the
different Vaga market models and they correspond to the phases of the economy that derives from
Hunt’s(1976) macroeconomic analysis.
Place Table 8 Here
Summary and Conclusions
The economic cycle and its attendant phases have a significant effect on investment performance. The
performance of stock portfolios and the S&P 500 varies during the phases. Portfolio construction based
on industries selected according to phase provides better overall performance than the no industry rotation
strategy. (The industry strategy outperforms the no industry strategy in four of five phases.)
The correspondence between Hunt’s[1976,1987] work and the results of this study indicates that the
study is successful at replicating Hunt's phases. While the phases originally derive from a macroeconomic
top-down approach, it is interesting that a bottom-up analysis using skewness, kurtosis and serial
correlations provides confirmation of the phases. Another interesting result is the correspondence
between Hunt's phases of the economic cycle and Vaga's[1990] coherent market approach. The popularity
of this approach is evident since Hunt[1987], Vaga[1994] and Stovall[1996] have written books on this
15
approach targeted at a general audience. All three books espoused switching between different types of
investments. Vaga’s switching mechanism depends on the type of market conditions, while Hunt’s and
Stovall’s switching mechanism depends on the phase of the economic cycle. The evidence presented in
this paper supports a viewpoint that the statistical behavior of the different market periods derives from
the general business cycle.
In addition, there is strong evidence that the underlying market structure is nonstationary (differing
returns during the Easeoff and Revival 1 phases) and that investors have to continually monitor the
market conditions for changes in the market structure. This provides additional evidence in support of
adaptive management processes rather than static management processes.
Finally, does knowledge of the business cycle improve investment performance? Does the market
rotate into and out of industries in response to changes in the business cycle? The empirical results
obtained in this paper indicate an affirmative answer to both questions.
16
References
Anderson, P., Arrow, Kenneth, and D. Pines, eds. (1988). Economy as an Evolving Complex System,
Addison-Wesley.
Ang, James S. and Jess H. Chua, 1979, “Composite Measures for the Evaluation of Investment
Performance.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14, 2, 361-384.
Arnott, Robert D. and William A. Copeland, 1985, "The Business Cycle and Security Selection."
Financial Analysts Journal, 41, 2, 26-32.
Abraham, Abraham and David L. Ikenberry, 1993, "The Individual Investor Around Nontrading Days,"
Review of Financial Studies, 6, 1, 155-189.
Bauman, W. Scott and Robert E. Miller, 1995, "Portfolio Performance Rankings in Stock Market Cycles,"
Financial Analysts Journal, 51, 2, 79-87.
Chen, Nai-Fu, Richard Roll and Stephen Ross, 1986, "Economic Forces and the Stock Market." Journal of
Business, 59, 3, 383-404.
Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber and M. Padberg, 1976, "Simple Rules for Optimal Portfolio Selection."
Journal of Finance, 31, 5, 1341-1357.
Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber and Thomas J. Urich, 1978, “Are Betas Best?”, Journal of Finance, 33,
5, 1375-1384.
Fishburn, Peter C., 1977, “Mean-Risk Analysis with Risk Associated with Below-Target Returns.”
American Economic Review, 67, 2, 116-126.
Harlow, W.V., 1991, "Asset Allocation in a Downside Risk Framework." Financial Analysts Journal, 47,
September/October, 28-40.
Hastings, N.A.J. and J.B. Peacock, 1975, Statistical Distributions: A Handbook for Students and
Practitioners, Halstead Press, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Hogan, William W. and James M. Warren, 1972, “Computation of the efficient boundary in the E-S
Portfolio Selection Model.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 7, 4, 1881-1896.
Hunt, Lacy H., 1976, Dynamics of Forecasting Financial Cycles: Theory, Technique and Implementation,
JAI Press, Greenwich, CT.
Hunt, Lacy H., 1987, A Time to be Rich, Rawson Associates, Macmillan, New York, NY.
Liano, Kartono, 1992, "Macroeconomic Events and Seasonality of Risk and Returns," Applied Financial
Economics, 2, 4, 205-210.
Liano, Kartono, and Benton E. Gup, 1989, "The Day-of-the-Week Effect in Stock Returns," Financial
Analyst Journal, 45, 4, 74-77.
Liano, Kartono, Gow-Cheng Huang and Benton E. Gup, 1993, "A Twist on the Monday Effect in Stock
Returns: A Note," Journal of Economics and Business, 45, 1, 61-67.
17
Markowitz, Harry M. 1991, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, Second Edition,
Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.
Moore, Geoffrey H., 1983, Business Cycles, Inflation and Forecasting, NBER Research Studies in
Business Cycles, No. 24, Ballinger Publishing, Cambridge, MA.
Murphy, Roy E., 1965, Adaptive Processes in Economic Systems. New York: Academic Press.
Nawrocki, David N., 1983, "A Comparison of Risk Measures When Used in a Simple Portfolio Selection
Heuristic." Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 10, 2, 183-194.
Nawrocki, David N., 1984, “Entropy, Bifurcation and Dynamic Market Disequilibrium.” The Financial
Review, 19, 2, 266-284.
Nawrocki, David N., 1990, "Tailoring Asset Allocation to the Individual Investor," International Review
of Economics and Business, 37, 10-11, 183-194.
Nawrocki, David N., 1995, "R/S Analysis and Long Term Dependence in Stock Market Indices."
Managerial Finance, 21, 7, 78-91.
Peters, Edgar E., 1991, Chaos and Order in the Capital Markets, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Peters, Edgar E., 1994, Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics,
New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Shannon, C.E. and W. Weaver, 1948, The Mathematical Theory of Communications, Urbana, IL:
University of Illinois.
Sharpe, William F., 1967, "A Linear Programming Algorithm for Mutual Fund Portfolio Selection."
Management Science, 14, 3, 499-510.
Stovall, Sam, 1996, Standard and Poors Guide to Sector Investing, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Vaga, Tonis, 1990, "The Coherent Market Hypothesis." Financial Analysts Journal, 46, 6, 36-49.
Vaga, Tonis, 1994, Profiting From Chaos, McGraw Hill, New York, NY.
18
Table 1 - Geometrically Linked Annualized Returns and Monthly SemiDeviations for
26 Years (1969-1994) for Various Asset Classes
-----------------------------------------------------------------
1969 to 1969 to 1974 to 1983 to
1994 1973 1982 1994
Asset Classes Total Period Vietnam Oil Crisis Recovery
-----------------------------------------------------------------
S&P 500 Stocks 10.17 -2.36 13.73 14.41
(3.00) (3.68) (2.73) (2.81)
Mid-Cap Stocks 11.73 -6.56 22.18 14.67
(3.55) (4.65) (3.18) (3.15)
Small-Cap Stocks 11.53 -10.50 28.29 12.71
(4.13) (5.29) (3.77) (3.70)
LB LT Govt. 7.65 0.04 7.72 11.62
(1.78) (0.98) (2.24) (1.73)
LB G/C Intermediate 7.71 1.18 9.52 9.83
(0.78) (0.68) (1.12) (0.56)
Gold 9.15 25.03 14.08 -1.16
(3.37) (2.75) (4.18) (3.00)
90 Day T-Bill 7.28 6.22 9.04 6.57
(0.07) (0.11) (0.14) (0.02)
CPI - Consumer Prices 5.77 6.49 8.25 3.69
(0.22) (0.21) (0.26) (0.15)
CPI - New Cars 3.88 3.02 6.05 2.84
(0.61) (0.99) (0.62) (0.35)
CPI - Food & Beverages 5.46 7.80 6.82 3.44
(0.33) (0.36) (0.45) (0.23)
CPI - Fuel 6.41 8.98 13.82 0.81
(0.87) (0.30) (0.45) (1.13)
Median House Prices 6.79 7.46 8.37 5.41
(2.42) (2.53) (2.00) (2.59)
Data sources include Lehman Brothers bond indexes, CRSP stock
datasets, and CITIBASE/Fame/DRI economic database.
19
Table 2 - Hunt's Phases of the General Economic Cycle
----------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 1 (EASEOFF) - Economy reaches a peak as defined by the NBER and real
GNP starts to decline. The decision rules that indicate the start of this
phase include: a 12 month percentage rate of change moving average for
industrial production turns negative, initial unemployment claims increase,
and nonfarm payrolls decline.
Phase 2 (PLUNGE) Real GNP declines as interest rates peak. The economy reaches
a trough as defined by the NBER. The decision rules that indicate the
start of this phase include: a 12 month rate of change moving average for
federal funds rates turns negative and a 6 month rate of change moving
average for the real monetary base turns positive.
Phase 3 (REVIVAL 1 or Early Revival) - Real GNP starts to increase.
The decision rules that indicate the start of this phase include: a 12 month
percentage rate of change for industrial production levels off towards a zero
percent change, initial unemployment claims decrease, and nonfarm payrolls
increase.
Phase 4 (REVIVAL 2 or Late Revival) - Real GNP recovers from the recession
The decision rules that indicate the start of this phase include: a 12 month
percentage rate of change for industrial production becomes positive and
nonfarm payrolls increase at a higher rate.
Phase 5 (ACCELERATE) - The economy continues to grow at a high rate prompting
the Federal Reserve to tighten credit, resulting in decreased consumer
spending while business investment continues to increase. The decision rules
that indicate the start of this phase include: a 6 month rate of change in
consumer prices turns positive, a 12 month rate of change in federal funds
rates turns positive, a 6 month rate of change moving average for the real
monetary base turns negative, and nonfarm payrolls increase at an even
higher rate.
Reference: Hunt(1976), The decision rules were determined using Hunt's
methodology with data from 1970 to 1986.
20
Table 3 - Dates of the US Business Cycle, Percentage Changes and Correlation
Coefficients for Macroeconomic Variables During Different Phases of
Business Cycle. (Monthly Data - January 1970 to December 1986)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Easeoff(1) Plunge(2) Revival 1(3) Revival 2(4) Accelerate(5)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Dates 12/69-4/70P 5/70-12/70T 1/71-5/71 6/71-10/72 11/72-3/73
4/73-9/74P 10/74-5/75T 6/75-12/75 1/72-2/77 3/77-3/79
4/79-4/80P 5/80-7/80T 8/80-12/80 1/81-8/81
9/81-10/81P 11/81-10/82 11/82-4/83T 5/83-10/83 11/83-4/84
5/84-10/84 11/84-8/86 9/86-12/86
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Annualized Percent Changes
S&P -14.59 24.74 22.33 6.34 -0.99
IP -0.92 -5.20 8.96 8.82 7.26
FYFF 22.49 -47.77 35.32 2.69 46.71
FYFF(-12) 44.68 -21.72 -36.61 -7.69 28.12
FMBASE -3.28 3.50 3.62 2.33 1.78
FMBASE(-6) -6.08 5.17 9.42 8.21 6.47
FMFBA -2.47 2.81 3.41 2.08 1.73
FM1DQ -4.95 4.54 2.91 3.18 0.14
LPNAG 1.85 -0.75 2.23 3.05 5.06
LUINC 60.37 7.27 -36.15 -6.05 -12.65
CPI 10.51 4.28 5.54 5.14 6.85
CPI-Energy 23.68 -2.12 4.21 5.77 7.12
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Correlations
S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP
S&P 1.00 .07 1.00 -.03 1.00 -.15 1.00 .34* 1.00 .20
IP .07 1.00 -.03 1.00 -.15 1.00 .34* 1.00 .20 1.00
FYFF -.07 .34* -.22* .42* -.14 .28* -.19* -.13 -.20 .01
FYFF(-12) -.03 .08 -.15 -.04 .01 .19 -.25* -.11 -.05 -.07
FMBASE .07 .22* -.05 .24* .24 -.41* .11 .36* -.23* -.17
FMBASE(-6) .06 .38* -.12 .50* .22 -.23 .02 .23* -.19 .03
FMFBA .17 .07 .06 .31* .25 -.41* .26* .36* .01 -.06
FM1DQ .24* .02 .16 .18* .30* -.18 .20* .05 .16 -.07
LPNAG .10 .51* .06 .76* -.43* .51* .46* .43* .03 .66*
LUINC -.30* -.63* .23* -.46* -.22 .31* -.32* -.34* -.13 -.20
CPI -.08 -.03 -.03 -.33* -.05 .56* -.25* -.31* .14 .03
CPI-Energy .11 -.10 .03 -.15 -.21 .05 -.04 -.17 .03 -.03
df 43 53 23 49 35
* indicates significance at 10%
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Citibase/Fame/DRI access codes are used to represent the various macroeconomic
variables. All time series are monthly and seasonally adjusted with the
exception of the S&P. All data are percentage changes and are nominal amounts
except where noted.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P S&P 500 Composite Index FMFBA Real Monetary Base (Fed)
IP Industrial Production FM1DQ Real M1 Money Supply
FYFF Federal Funds Rate of Change LPNAG Non-Farm Payroll
FYFF(-12) Fed Funds 12 Mo. Rate of Change LUINC Initial Unemployment
FMBASE Real Monetary Base (St.Louis Fed) CPI Consumer Price Index
FMBASE(-6) Real Monetary Base - 6 Mo. ROC CPI-Energy Consumer Energy Prices
A NBER defined peak (P) or trough (T) appeared during this period.
21
Table 4 - Characteristics of Vaga's Different Types of Market Behavior
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Market
Behavior Skewness Kurtosis Return Risk Mode
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Chaotic Significant Leptokurtic Low High Bimodal
Skewness
Coherent Significant Leptokurtic High Low Unimodal
Negative
Skewness
Transition Symmetric Platykurtic Varying Varying Unimodal
Random Walk Symmetric Mesokurtic Average Average Unimodal
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Source: Vaga[1990]
Leptokurtic - Peaked probability distribution
Platykurtic - Flat probability distribution
Mesokurtic - Normal distribution
---------------------------------------------------------------------
22
Table 5 - 15 Industries Selected by Ranking by R/LPM Ratio for the Five Phases of the
Economic Cycle (1970-1986). All R/LPM Ratios are Positive.
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Easeoff Phase 1 Plunge Phase 2 Revival 1 Phase 3
---------------------------------------------------------------------
GOLD MINING UTILITY STOCKS ELECTRIC POWER
OIL-GAS DRILLING CONSUMER GOODS FOODS
TOBACCO FOODS TEXTILE-APPAREL MFRS
CHEM-SPECIALTY BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK PAPER & FOREST PRODUCTS
CHEM-DIVERSIFIED TOBACCO CONTAINERS-PAPER
OIL-DOMESTIC PUBLISHING PUBLISHING
HOUSEWARES DRUGS PUBLISHING-NEWSPAPERS
CONTAINERS-METAL MEDICAL PRODUCTS CHEMICALS
ALUMINUM HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS CHEMICALS-DIVERSIFIED
COMMUN.EQUIP.MFR COSMETICS OIL-INTERNATIONAL
ELECTRONICS-DEFENSE OIL-INTERNATIONAL SHOES
AEROSPACE/DEFENSE SHOES CONTAINERS-METAL&GLASS
RAILROADS HOUSEHOLD FURNISHINGS STEEL
TRANSPORTATION-MISC AUTO PARTS-AFTERMKT POLLUTION CONTROL
TELEPHONE MANUFACTURED HOUSING HOUSEHOLD FURN&APPL
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Revival 2 Phase 4 Accelerate Phase 5
-------------------------------------------------------------------
ELECTRIC POWER CAPITAL GOODS
OIL&GAS DRILLING GOLD MINING
BEVERAGES-ALCOHOLIC MACHINE TOOLS
BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK OILWELL EQUIP&SERVICE
PUBLISHING-NEWSPAPERS OIL&GAS DRILLING
HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK
OILWELL EQUIP&SERVICE TOBACCO
MACHINE TOOLS CONTAINERS-PAPER
POLLUTION CONTROL DRUGS
ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS
HOUSEHOLD FURN&APPL COSMETICS
COMM. EQUIP MFR CHEMICALS-DIVERSIFIED
ELECTRONICS-DEFENSE OIL-DOMESTIC
AUTOMOBILES OIL-INTERNATIONAL
AUTO PARTS-AFTER MKT COMPUTER SYSTEMS
-------------------------------------------------------------------
23
Table 6 - Historic Performance of R/LPM Heuristic, Covariance Optimization and
Cosemivariance Optimization (1958-1987)
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Revision Best LPM R/LPM Covariance Cosemivariance
Period Degree Risk-Return Risk-Return Risk-Return
--------------------------------------------------------------------
3 1.2 0.2287 0.1536 0.1505
6 1.0 0.2430 0.1636 0.1736
12 1.6 0.2363 0.1494 0.1541
24 1.4 0.2221 0.1383 0.1636
36 2.8 0.2201 0.1230 0.1744
48 4.6 0.2467 0.0842 0.1490
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Revision Period indicates that the portfolios were revised every 3,
6, 12, 24, 36, and 48 months. Transaction costs of 1% were
assessed during each revision.
Best LPM Degree indicates the LPM degree that provided the best risk-
return performance for the particular revision strategy.
Risk-Return is measured using the reward to semivariability ratio
(R/SV).
--------------------------------------------------------------------
24
Table 7 - Quarterly Return Values (In Per Cent) for the Period 3/4/1988 to
2/10/1995 Using Portfolios Selected According to Industry and Phase of
Economic Cycle. 20 Asset Portfolios Selected Using the R/LPM Heuristic
and a Historic 104 Week Period.
-------------------------------------------------------------------
R/LPM
Per Begin EndDate S&P500 20 Asset Skew Kurt Phase TSerCor
-------------------------------------------------------------------
1 880304 880513 -2.16 5.69 -1.2452* 6.3045 5 1.2575
2 880520 880819 1.35 4.92 -1.2904* 6.4832 5 1.4942*
3 880826 881111 2.95 2.69 -1.2253* 6.4769 5 1.2928*
4 881118 890217 10.77 8.78 -1.1482* 6.6135 1 1.2766
5 890224 890512 5.75 16.71 -1.2241* 6.9247 1 1.1697
6 890519 890818 10.26 18.68 -1.3078* 7.2141 1 1.0979
7 890825 891110 -2.00 5.55 -1.3361* 7.3787 1 1.0071
8 891117 900216 -1.88 -5.42 -.4724* 4.2490 2 -2.7017*
9 900223 900511 5.80 13.78 -.7213* 4.4377 2 -2.8019*
10 900518 900817 -6.87 -1.48 -.6377* 4.3465 2 -2.1705* P
11 900824 901109 -4.30 -4.99 -.7462* 4.0964 2 -1.7145*
12 901116 910215 17.63 21.73 -.6324* 3.6199 2 -2.3073*
13 910222 910510 1.81 2.84 -.3729 3.3695 2 -1.4940* T
14 910517 910802 3.04 6.88 -.3289 3.4657 3 -1.7066*
15 910809 911108 1.48 11.80 -.2441 3.4611 3 -1.6667*
16 911115 920214 4.99 5.53 .0863 2.7983 4 -.6462
17 920221 920508 .87 6.92 .2442 2.7658 4 -.1229
18 920515 920807 .68 8.50 .2675 3.0080 4 -.2968
19 920814 921106 -.31 3.85 .3047 3.2201 4 -.8695
20 921113 930219 3.99 15.74 .6342* 3.4456 4 .1902
21 930226 930507 1.86 2.48 .3824 3.1078 4 -.5334
22 930514 930806 1.44 5.31 .3478 3.1640 4 -.8014
23 930813 931105 2.43 -3.99 .4362 3.6096 4 -.5644
24 931112 940218 1.77 2.87 .4160 3.9379 4 -.3526
25 940218 940506 -4.25 -5.82 -.0480 2.9348 5 -2.3499*
26 940513 940812 3.16 -2.22 -.2545 3.3402 5 -1.3995*
27 940819 941111 .09 4.10 -.6528* 3.8141 5 -1.1435
28 941118 950210 4.13 3.36 -.5194* 3.5421 5 -2.3490*
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Frequency(R20 > Rm) 20
Binomial Probability 0.0188 (n=28 p=0.5)
* - indicates statistical significance for 10% level of significance.
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Aggregate Statistic
S&P 500 R/LPM 20 Asset
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Weekly Geometric Mean 0.1673% 0.3855%
Standard Deviation 1.6917 2.2574
Reward/Variability (R/V) 0.0377 0.1249
Semideviation 1.1958 1.5033
Reward/Semideviation (R/SV) 0.1467 0.2645
Annualized Return 9.0805 22.1486
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Per - Period Number
P and T are NBER Defined Peaks and Troughs
TSerCor - T-statistic for one week lag serial correlation on S&P500
Skew - Skewness
Kurt - Kurtosis
R20 - 20 Asset R/LPM Portfolio
Rm - S&P 500 Return
25
Table 8 - Performance Results for the Period March 3, 1988 to February 10, 1995
for Total Period and Different Phases
__________________________________________________________________
Total Period - Number of Observations: 363 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 9.08% 1.69% 1.20% .1467 -0.19* 4.02 -2.85*
No Indust 18.56 2.51 1.63 .2013 -0.12 3.83 -0.56
Industry 22.15 2.26 1.50 .2645#-0.33* 4.57 -2.35*
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 1 - Number of Observations: 47 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 26.69% 1.93% 1.40% .3267 -1.49* 6.41 -3.20* Coherent
No Indust 39.63 2.21 1.50 .4290 -1.35* 5.65 -0.22
Industry 57.79 2.18 1.29 .6933#-0.72* 3.88 -1.99*
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 2 - Number of Observations: 79 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 8.61% 2.13% 1.39% .1143 0.08 2.63 -0.19 Random
No Indust 19.36 2.88 1.86 .1829 -0.09 3.10 -0.20
Industry 17.83 2.65 1.72 .1837#-0.19 3.90 -0.71
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 3 - Number of Observations: 26 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 -7.63% 1.53% 1.13% -.1303 0.14 2.01 -0.62 Transition
No Indust 37.12 2.68 1.46 .4173# 0.30 3.20 -0.53
Indust 12.86 2.25 1.32 .1770 0.49 2.85 -0.21
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 4 - Number of Observations: 113 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 11.87% 1.24% 0.73% .2968 0.45* 4.32 -0.93 Coherent
No Indust 25.71 2.43 1.42 .3096 0.21 4.28 -0.34
Indust 27.35 1.78 1.04 .4481#-0.13 3.92 -0.38
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 5 - Number of Observations: 98 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
-------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 3.38% 1.69% 1.18% .0540 -0.08 3.61 -1.70* Chaotic
No Indust -1.96 2.36 1.75 -.0216 -0.26 3.47 -0.34
Indust 8.27 2.45 1.73 .0881#-0.46* 4.95 -1.93*
-------------------------------------------------------------------
# - Indicates best risk-return performance.
* - Indicates statistical significance for 10% level of significance.
AnnRet - Annualized return.
StdDev - Monthly standard deviation in per cent.
SemiDev - Monthly semideviation (square root of semivariance).
R/V - Reward to variability ratio (using standard deviation).
R/SV - Reward to semivariability ratio (using semideviation).
Skew - Skewness of portfolio returns.
Kurt - Kurtosis of portfolio returns.
T-Test - T-test of 104 week serial correlations of the S&P 500.