Phase of the Business Cycle and Portfolio Management good

background image

Phase of the Business Cycle and Portfolio Management

David Nawrocki

Professor of Finance

Department of Finance

College of Commerce and Finance

Villanova, PA 19085 USA

610-489-7520 Voice and Fax

610-519-4323 Office and Voice Mail

610-489-0750 Home

David.Nawrocki@Villanova.Edu

NawrockiD@aol.com

William Carter

The QInsight Group

San Diego, CA

619-295-9292 Office

wcarter@qinsight.com

Preliminary: Do not quote without permission of the authors.

The QInsight Group assumes no responsibility for the views or opinions expressed in this paper.
The authors bear full responsibility for the views and opinions expressed in this paper. The
performance results are provided as part of an academic study and are not to be construed as
expectations of future performance.

March 1997

background image

2

Phase of the Business Cycle and Portfolio Management

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to explore the business cycle and to see whether it influences portfolio
performance. Hunt[1976] provides the econometric work that serves as the basis for determining the
phase of the cycle. The study uses the Standard & Poors industry indexes, individual security data and
macroeconomic data to study the business cycle. The tests include a portfolio strategy that switches
between industries based on the phase of the economy. The paper concludes that the business cycle
influences the performance of stock portfolios and that the phases of the business cycle relate to the phases
in Vaga's[1990] Coherent Market Hypothesis.

Introduction

The relationship between economic activity and cyclical behavior in the money and capital markets has

not received a great deal of attention in the finance literature. Arnott and Copeland[1985] demonstrate

that the business cycle has a significant effect on security returns. Chen, Roll and Ross[1986] determine

that certain macroeconomic variables (industrial production, changes in the yield curve, and expected

inflation) are significant indicators of changes in stock returns. In addition, Moore[1983] explores the

relationship between inflation and business cycles.

Recently, Peters[1991,1994] using rescaled range (R/S) analysis finds evidence of long term

nonperiodic cycles in stock returns that average approximately 48 months in duration. Nawrocki[1995]

confirms this result but finds that the cycle is dependent on changes in the money supply and industrial

production.

Other academic studies focus on the effect that the economic cycle has on the microstructure of the

market, (e.g., Abraham and Ikenberry[1994], Liano[1992], Liano and Gup[1989], and Liano, Huang and

Gup[1993]). Recently, Bauman and Miller[1995] find that the ranking of investment performance is

more consistent over time with complete stock market cycles evaluations rather than market cycle subset

evaluations. Bauman and Miller differ from other studies in that they study the peak to peak stock market

cycle rather than the peak to peak business cycle as measured by industrial production. Stovall(1996)

takes an additional step and breaks the business cycle into five phases. Using the S&P Industry Indexes,

background image

3

he is able to demonstrate that different industries dominate (in terms of total return) during each phase.

Stovall concludes that an industry sector rotation strategy based on the business cycle will improve

investment performance.

The major questions to be answered are: Is knowledge of the business cycle necessary in order to

manage investment portfolios? Does the stock market rotate into and out of industries in response to

changes in the business cycle?

The concept of a business cycle is interesting. One position is that it is generated by a time-varying

parameter model. As parameters (technology, preferences, rate of financial innovation) of the model

change it can experience different states of nature. The changing parameters represent “surprise” to the

system which must adapt to the parameters. (The formal definition of information arrival in Shannon and

Weaver’s, 1947, information theory is for a message to have information content it must represent

“surprise” to the receiver of the message.) If the business cycle can be forecasted, there would be no

business cycle. Economic agents anticipating the forecasted parameter changes will make appropriate

adjustments to minimize the impact of the changes, hence, no cycle. This view of the economy as

constantly evolving over time through different states of nature with time-varying parameters is described

in Nawrocki(1984), Anderson, Arrow and Pines(1988) and Vaga(1990, 1994).

Vaga[1990,1994], in particular, takes an interesting approach describing the stock market as moving

through different types of market behavior. Vaga's market phases include random walk markets,

transition markets, coherent markets and chaotic markets. Vaga identifies the statistical properties of

each market type. One perspective of this paper is whether Vaga’s market phases relate to the business

cycle.

Even with this interest in the area of business cycles, Hunt[1976] is the only study that stresses the

econometric relationship between macroeconomic variables to detect transition points where the business

cycle transitions to new states of nature. Hunt studies macrovariables such as the federal funds rates,

capital market yields, business credit demands, unemployment claims, non-farm payroll, inflation, and

monetary and reserve aggregates. The relationships between these variables help determine the different

phases of the economic cycle. The purpose of Hunt’s work is to identify the change in the business cycle,

background image

4

not to forecast it. The first priority of this paper is to see whether Hunt’s methodology is replicable to

identify different phases in the economic cycle.

Identifying the phases of the economy allows the determination of which industries perform best

during individual phases. Therefore, a portfolio strategy that switches between industries will be

backtested to see whether the phase information is useful in the construction of portfolios. This paper

differs from previous work since it breaks the business cycle into its component phases and uses an

industry rotation strategy to take advantage of the individual phases of an economic cycle. Specifically,

the study utilizes the 1970-1986 period to identify the phases of the economy and the resulting industry

performance. A performance test of the industry rotation strategy then utilizes the 1988-1995 period.

(The year 1987 is not in the study since the market crash of 1987 results in highly skewed, leptokurtic

distributions for that period. It is realistic that an investment manager in March 1988 would make the

same decision after looking at the distributions with and without 1987.) The structure of the study

provides a holdout (out of sample) period and avoids the “look ahead” bias that is possible with empirical

backtests of investment strategies. The “look ahead” bias includes the problems of “data mining” or “data

snooping”.

The next section of the paper addresses the methodology used in the study, while the discussion of the

empirical results follows. The final section presents the conclusions of the paper.

Methodology

The portfolio strategy consists of the following steps:

Statistical Analysis to Determine Phases of the Business Cycle.

The Determination of the Best Industry Performance for each Phase of the Cycle.

Portfolio Selection Algorithm to Select 20 Asset Portfolio for Each Phase of the Cycle.

The Data

The data include monthly percentage return data for the S&P 500 Composite index as well as for over

100 S&P Industry indexes obtained from Standard & Poors. The data also includes macroeconomic

variables from the Citibase/Fame/DRI database. This data is available for the period starting

background image

5

in January 1970 and ending in June 1994. The test of the industry rotation model uses weekly relative

return data for 1510 stocks for the period March 1988 to February 1995. A screening procedure results in

the sample of 1510 stocks. In order to control liquidity costs, stocks with prices under $10 per share and

market capitalization under $250 million are not in the sample. To handle any additional implicit trading

costs, the transaction fee during portfolio revisions is 0.5% which is higher than the 0.2-0.3% available

through discount brokers to larger accounts (such as an investment manager or a mutual fund).

Statistical Analysis

The period from 1969 to 1994 is an interesting period. As demonstrated in Table 1, there were three

distinct phases in the US economy during this period. The first period is a period of increasing inflation

because of the Vietnam War and the failure of the US government to raise taxes to pay for the war. This

period is notable for increasing prices particularly fuel prices. To make matters worse, stocks and bonds

exhibit very low or negative returns, thus providing negative changes in purchasing power when investing

in financial assets. A tangible asset, gold, is the biggest gainer. However, an investor should note that the

US drops the gold standard on international payments during this period and allows gold to float with the

market prices. The next period is easy to pick because of the Arab-Israeli war in 1973 and the resulting

oil embargo. This is the period of the oil crisis with double digit increases in energy prices over the rest of

the decade. The stock market rebounds sharply during this period. However, on a real basis, it is only

recovering from the 1969-1973 decline. Gold maintains its high real rate of return. After the 1979 oil

crisis and the double dip recessions of 1980-82, the US economy entered into its current phase. Factors

important in selecting 1983 to start this period include the non-effect of the Iraq-Iran war on fuel prices

and the recovery of the US economy from the double-dip recessions. Inflation is below average and

approaches the inflation rates of the late 1950s and early 1960s. Inflation in fuel prices is nonexistent.

On a real basis, fuel prices decline since 1982. Stocks and bonds provide high real returns during this

period while tangible assets like gold lose purchasing power.

Place Table 1 Here

background image

6

The Hunt(1976) methodology for determining phases of the economy studies the economic cycle for

structural changes. Table 2 provides the definitions of Hunt’s five phases of the economic cycle, and the

behavior of macroeconomic variables during these phases and the resulting decision rules used to

determine a phase change.

Place Table 2 Here

Table 3 presents the results of utilizing Hunt’s methodology for the period from 1970 to 1986. The

peaks and troughs are from the NBER’s Survey of Current Business. The NBER does not publish the

official peak and trough dates until well after the event. Therefore, an investment strategy cannot be

formulated using the NBER announcements. The macroeconomic variables have to be studied in order to

identify the phase of the business cycle at the time of the phase change. Hunt’s methodology consists of

following macroeconomic statistics that are relatively hard numbers. That is, they are not based on

sampling and are usually not subject to revision. Even if the variable is subsequently revised, only the

originally announced value is included in this study. The variables consist of money supply, interest rates,

and unemployment claims. Sample variables consist of inflation, non-farm payroll, and industrial

production. These variables are published on a monthly basis and are rarely revised. Hunt uses

econometric relationships, correlations, reversals in variables, and time series analysis to determine when

a change in phase has taken place. (It is not possible to describe Hunt’s methodology in a short research

paper. Hunt(1976) requires an entire book to develop and explain the methodology.) The method is

adaptive, not a proactive forecasting technique. Vaga(1990) also provides statistical tools such as

skewness, kurtosis and serial correlations to determine market phases.

The easeoff and plunge phases are consistent with the peaks and troughs from the Survey through

1982. (The 11/82 trough is missed by one month.) The easeoff and plunge period noted in 1984 did not

meet the NBER’s definition but it did meet Hunt’s macroeconomic conditions. (In addition, the

appropriate industry rotation did occur in the stock market.) This is a strong confirmation of Hunt’s

methodology since the NBER defined peaks and troughs are not known until months after his

methodology indicates the phase change. Knowing the actual dates of the peaks and troughs is not

necessary. It is sufficient to know the general phase in which the peak or trough takes place in order to

background image

7

benefit from the sector rotation strategy. The economy reaches a peak during the Easeoff phase. At this

point the Federal Reserve is following a tight monetary policy that is characterized by large increases in

the federal funds rate and decreases in the monetary aggregates. Growth in non-farm payroll slows and

there is an increase in initial unemployment claims. Therefore, industrial production reaches a peak and

starts to fall. In the meantime, inflation peaks.

The economy reaches a trough during the Plunge phase. Industrial production declines as does non-

farm payroll. Initial unemployment claims continue to increase. The Federal Reserve, meanwhile, is

increasing monetary aggregates and decreasing the federal funds rate in an attempt to stimulate the

economy. Inflation slows to its lowest level during the economic cycle. The stock market exhibits very

high returns as it is anticipating the economic revival as a result of the Federal Reserve policy.

The early revival (Revival1) starts with large increases in industrial production and increasing federal

funds rates. The monetary aggregates continue to grow along with non-farm payroll. Initial

unemployment claims drop drastically. Inflation ticks up a bit. Again the stock market exhibits high

returns.

The transition to the late revival (Revival2) exhibits decreasing stock market returns, slower growth

in the monetary aggregates and moderating inflation. Generally, the economy is very stable during this

period with stable growth in industrial production and stable prices. The stock market returns while lower

are also very stable.

An increase in inflation and a restrictive Federal Reserve monetary policy mark the beginning of the

Accelerate phase. The federal funds rates increase rapidly, and the growth in the monetary aggregates

declines drastically. The overheating economy is evident by the largest gains during the cycle in nonfarm

payrolls and large drops in initial unemployment claims. Industrial production is still increasing at a high

rate, but is starting to slow because of the restrictive Federal Reserve policy. The stock market starts to

decline in anticipation of a future recession.

Table 3 also provides the econometric performance during these phases. During the Easeoff period,

there is a correlation between the federal funds rate, the monetary base, the employment numbers and

industrial production. These same variables along with inflation and the M1 money supply are significant

background image

8

relative to industrial production during the Plunge phase. Note that information concerning the transition

to a new phase is not available until after the transition. Analysts have to watch for changing correlations

as well as changing macroeconomic variables.

The federal funds rate, the monetary base, employment numbers and inflation are the important

variables to watch during the transition to a Revival 1 phase. The important variables during the revival

2 phase are changes in monetary base, employment numbers and inflation. The federal funds rate is not a

factor. The only factor that is significant during the Accelerate phase is the non-farm payroll. The

sudden acceleration of the nonfarm payroll as well as slowing growth in the real monetary base signifies a

change in the stock market.

Each phase lasts for at least six months. This introduces the point that it is not necessary to forecast

the phase changes but rather to adapt to changes in economic conditions. There is time in each phase to

benefit from the economic conditions of the phase. The adaptation is necessary since most of the

macroeconomic data is not available to the markets until weeks after the change in economic conditions.

Place Table 3 Here

Vaga’s Stock Market Phases

Vaga(1990,1994) proposes that the stock market moves through distinctive phases over time. Vaga

describes the phases statistically. Table 4 summarizes Vaga’s four phases of the stock market. Vaga’s

descriptions derive from the return, risk, skewness and kurtosis of the stock market returns. As can be

seen in Table 4, investors do best in coherent markets and random walk markets. It is best to avoid

chaotic markets and transition markets. The statistical properties of the stock market during the different

phases of the economy are interesting given Vaga’s work. The random walk exhibits average returns and

average risk levels. As is common with random walk conditions, the best strategy is to buy and hold a

diversified portfolio. A coherent market by definition is easy to forecast. Diversified portfolios provide

high returns and low risk. In addition, investors may utilize forecasting techniques to increase returns.

The transition market occurs as the market moves from coherent to chaotic to random. It is a difficult

market period for investors depending on the transition. A chaotic market provides the unhappy

combination of low returns and high risk.

background image

9

Place Table 4 Here

Industry Performance

Next, using monthly data from January 1970 to December 1986, the risk-return performance ranks the

S&P industry indexes for each of the five phases. (December 1986 was the end of a Revival 2 phase. The

next phase continued past the simulation starting point of March 1988.) A more sophisticated measure of

risk, the reward-to-lower partial moment (R/LPM) ratio, provides a ranking of the industry indexes.

Research conducted by Ang and Chua[1979], Nawrocki(1983), and Harlow[1991] support the use of LPM

in a portfolio allocation process because of its statistical superiority over the variance measure. For the

interested reader, Markowitz[1991, 374-376] provides a comprehensive bibliography of

semivariance/lower partial moment research. The n-degree lower partial moment is a measure of

downside risk where the semivariance is a special case (n=2). Fishburn(1977) provides the theoretical

arguments for using the n-degree lower partial moment. Table 5 lists the top 15 industries as ranked by

the R/LPM for each phase.

Place Table 5 Here

Portfolio Selection Algorithms

Operations research has a long history of using heuristic algorithms because of computational

complexity of optimal algorithms. Typically, the heuristic algorithm derives mathematically from the

optimal algorithm, thus providing replicable results. The advantage of the heuristic algorithm is usually

that it is simpler and less costly to implement. With modern microcomputers, this is not the important

factor of twenty-five years ago. Using historical data, an optimal quadratic code will provide a more

efficient portfolio set than a heuristic algorithm. However, portfolio management does not take place in

the past but rather in the future. Therefore, the question becomes which algorithm, heuristic or optimal,

provides the best portfolio management performance. Statistical tests by Elton, Gruber and Urich[1978]

and economic tests by Nawrocki[1990] demonstrate that heuristic algorithms provide better ex post

performance than optimal algorithms.

This study employs the R/LPM heuristic algorithm because of its historic performance and because it is

easy to implement with maximum allocation constraints. This simple heuristic algorithm derives from

background image

10

Sharpe's[1967] idea that a heuristic algorithm can ignore intercorrelations between securities if the

number of securities in the portfolio is sufficiently large (20 or more). Sharpe proposes this algorithm in

order to handle maximum investment constraints necessary for mutual fund operations. The resulting

algorithm is as follows:

Z

i

= (R

i

-R

f

)/(LPM

n

), (1)

where R

i

is the return on security i, R

f

is the riskfree rate of return and LPM

n

is the n-degree lower

partial moment. The allocations represent a weighting according to the R/LPM ratio. The allocations

compute as follows:

k
X

i

= Z

i

/

Σ

Z

j

for all Z

j

> 0, (2)

j=1

where k is the number of securities where Z

i

> 0. The portfolio heuristic algorithm in this study uses

weekly security relative returns and treasury bill relative returns as the target return.

Selecting the parameters of the R/LPM portfolio algorithm is important in order to avoid “data

snooping” or “look ahead” bias. A random sample of 150 securities from the CRSP dataset for the period

1958 to 1987 provides a backtest. (The algorithm study ends in 1987 so that the industry rotation study

commencing in 1988 avoids the “look ahead” bias.) The R/LPM heuristic algorithm uses 3, 6, 12, 24, 36

and 48 month revision periods to test for the appropriate parameters. An optimal covariance algorithm

(Markowitz, 1991)and an optimal cosemivariance algorithm (Hogan & Warren, 1972) are also in the

study. A summary of the results is in Table 6. For all revision periods, the LPM heuristic algorithm

outperforms the optimal algorithms on a risk-return basis. In addition, the table reports the degree of the

LPM that achieves the maximum performance. This paper concerns itself with quarterly revision as the

economic data for each quarter becomes available. For three month revisions, a degree of 1.2 provides the

best performance for the LPM heuristic.

Place Table 6 Here

background image

11

Availability of Economic Data for Determining Phases

Determining the phase of the economic cycle is a reactive (adaptive) process. There is a lag in the

time from when the economy changes phases to the time when the economic data indicates the change.

As a result, the investment strategy is an adaptive strategy rather than a proactive forecasting strategy.

Because of the time lag in obtaining economic data, investment decisions that result from this data will

not occur at the end of a calendar quarter. There is a lag until the information is available. Therefore,

quarterly revision decisions occur in the middle of February, May, August and November. This

investment strategy follows a Murphy(1965) Type II adaptive control process. A Type II process consists

of a decision vector which is dependent on an environmental vector (current state of nature) and a

historical information vector (previous states of nature). The decision is made with a one period lag since

the decision cannot be made without the arrival of the new information. This represents a more realistic

application of the investment strategy and improves the validity of the backtest.

Investment Strategies

The investment strategies employed in this study include:

S&P500 which is a buy and hold in the S&P 500 composite index during each quarter.

No Indust which is a 20 asset R/LPM heuristic algorithm portfolio (equations 1 and 2) selected from

the entire database of 1510 stocks. There is no implementation of industry selection by phase.

Industry which is a 20 asset R/LPM heuristic algorithm portfolio selected from the 1510 stocks

database except the stocks are screened by the appropriate industries for the current economic phase..

If the stock is a member of an appropriate industry for the current phase, then its inclusion into the

portfolio is determined by its R/LPM ratio (equations 1 and 2).

All investment strategies are buy-and-hold during the quarter without any implementation of stop loss or

other portfolio insurance schemes. Input statistics for the algorithm derive from a historic period of the

previous 104 weeks. Backtesting during the 1981-86 period indicates that the 104 week historic period

provides the best forecasting performance.

background image

12

Empirical Results

Quarterly Performance Results

Table 7 presents the first set of out-of-sample results from 1988 to 1995. On an aggregate basis, the

R/LPM 20 asset portfolios with industry rotation outperform the S&P index over the seven year period

both in terms of return and risk-return. The S&P index does provide lower risk than the R/LPM portfolios

at the cost of reduced returns and risk-return performance. On an individual quarter basis, the R/LPM 20

asset portfolio outperforms the S&P 500 index during 20 of 28 quarters. This is statistically significant

using a binomial test of significance where p=0.5 is the null hypothesis (0.0188). The binomial test uses a

normal approximation with a mean, np, and the variance, np(1-p) to compute the appropriate

probabilities [Hastings and Peacock, 1975]. The normal approximation applies whenever n>20 and np>5

and n(1-p) >5.

The interesting results in Table 7 are the moving 104 week calculations of skewness, kurtosis, and the

one week lag serial correlations. During phases 2, 3, and 5 (plunge, early revival, accelerate), the 104

week serial correlations are significantly negative. There are insignificant serial correlations during

Phases 1 and 4. The skewness and kurtosis numbers are especially interesting. Phases 1, 2, and 5 exhibit

significantly negative skewness and are leptokurtic while phases 3 and 4 have insignificant skewness and

kurtosis values close to 3.0. The transition from Easeoff (1) to Plunge(2) is striking. The skewness and

kurtosis numbers drop drastically while the serial correlation suddenly becomes significantly negative.

The transition from Plunge(2) to Revival 1(3) occurs with skewness values turning insignificant. The

transition from Revival 1(3) to Revival 2(4) again is sudden with the serial correlations becoming

insignificant. A switch back to significant negative serial correlations marks the beginning of the

Accelerate(5) phase.

Phase 3, early revival, seems to be a transition period since it has significant negative serial correlation

while serial correlations in phase 4, late Revival, are insignificant. Phase 4 provides results close to a

random walk, i.e., insignificant serial correlation and distributions that are approximately normal. These

results correspond to Vaga's[1990] coherent market hypothesis. Note that in Table 4, leptokurtic

background image

13

distributions with significant skewness characterize Vaga's coherent and chaotic markets, while the

random walk market is symmetric and mesokurtic (kurtosis = 3.0).

The correspondence between the phases determined by Hunt’s methodology and the statistics determining

Vaga’s market states is important. It indicates that the statistical stages of Vaga’s coherent market model

have an economic (business cycle) foundation.

Place Table 7 Here

Performance Results by Phase

To further explore this result, Table 8 presents the aggregate results for the trading strategies in the

five phases. The R/LPM portfolio selection employs both industry selection and no industry selection for

security screening. Overall, the industry rotation strategy performs better than the other investment

strategies (except for Phase 3 - Revival 1).

In phase 1, Easeoff, the industry selection using historic 104 week estimates provides the best

performance. Significant negative skewness, a high degree of kurtosis and significant serial correlation

characterize the first phase. Of the five phases, phase 1 provides the highest returns, which is consistent

with the high returns during the 1983-1994 period in Table 1. Phase 1 provides a different result during

the last economic cycle than it did during the 1970s and early 1980s with high positive returns during the

recent period and negative returns during the 1970-1986 period. While phase 1 does not exhibit the low

risk that Vaga identifies with a coherent market, it has the best risk-return performance of the five phases

and significant serial correlation. As such it meets the criteria of a Vaga coherent market.

Phase 2, Plunge, provides results consistent with a Vaga random walk market: symmetric

distributions, kurtosis values close to 3.0 and insignificant serial correlation. The risk-return performance

is less than the average for the total period. The industry selected portfolios again provide the best risk-

return performance.

A Vaga transition market period characterizes phase 3, Revival 1, because of the kurtosis value for the

S&P 500 index is 2.0 (platykurtic). The distributions are symmetric and there is very low serial

correlation. The R/LPM heuristic without industry selection provides the best risk-return performance.

background image

14

The S&P return does not follow the past history exhibiting losses rather than the large gains available

during the 1970-1986 period.

Phase 4, Revival 2, is the coherent market period that Vaga speaks so highly about in his work since

it exhibits higher than average returns and lower than average risks. There is also the significantly

skewed and leptokurtic distributions identified by Vaga. The industry selection provides the best risk-

return performance.

Phase 5, Accelerate, is an appropriate time for a portfolio manager to take a vacation. It exhibits the

worst risk-return performance as well as the lowest overall returns. This is very interesting result since

Hunt(1987) discusses how his investment managers take Caribbean vacations during the Accelerate

phase. The distributions are slightly leptokurtic with some serial correlation. Again the industry

selection provides the best performance. The pattern of increasing risk and lower return fit Vaga's

description of a chaotic market period. All of the phases exhibit the statistical characteristics of the

different Vaga market models and they correspond to the phases of the economy that derives from

Hunt’s(1976) macroeconomic analysis.

Place Table 8 Here

Summary and Conclusions

The economic cycle and its attendant phases have a significant effect on investment performance. The

performance of stock portfolios and the S&P 500 varies during the phases. Portfolio construction based

on industries selected according to phase provides better overall performance than the no industry rotation

strategy. (The industry strategy outperforms the no industry strategy in four of five phases.)

The correspondence between Hunt’s[1976,1987] work and the results of this study indicates that the

study is successful at replicating Hunt's phases. While the phases originally derive from a macroeconomic

top-down approach, it is interesting that a bottom-up analysis using skewness, kurtosis and serial

correlations provides confirmation of the phases. Another interesting result is the correspondence

between Hunt's phases of the economic cycle and Vaga's[1990] coherent market approach. The popularity

of this approach is evident since Hunt[1987], Vaga[1994] and Stovall[1996] have written books on this

background image

15

approach targeted at a general audience. All three books espoused switching between different types of

investments. Vaga’s switching mechanism depends on the type of market conditions, while Hunt’s and

Stovall’s switching mechanism depends on the phase of the economic cycle. The evidence presented in

this paper supports a viewpoint that the statistical behavior of the different market periods derives from

the general business cycle.

In addition, there is strong evidence that the underlying market structure is nonstationary (differing

returns during the Easeoff and Revival 1 phases) and that investors have to continually monitor the

market conditions for changes in the market structure. This provides additional evidence in support of

adaptive management processes rather than static management processes.

Finally, does knowledge of the business cycle improve investment performance? Does the market

rotate into and out of industries in response to changes in the business cycle? The empirical results

obtained in this paper indicate an affirmative answer to both questions.

background image

16

References

Anderson, P., Arrow, Kenneth, and D. Pines, eds. (1988). Economy as an Evolving Complex System,
Addison-Wesley.

Ang, James S. and Jess H. Chua, 1979, “Composite Measures for the Evaluation of Investment
Performance.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14, 2, 361-384.

Arnott, Robert D. and William A. Copeland, 1985, "The Business Cycle and Security Selection."
Financial Analysts Journal, 41, 2, 26-32.

Abraham, Abraham and David L. Ikenberry, 1993, "The Individual Investor Around Nontrading Days,"
Review of Financial Studies, 6, 1, 155-189.

Bauman, W. Scott and Robert E. Miller, 1995, "Portfolio Performance Rankings in Stock Market Cycles,"
Financial Analysts Journal, 51, 2, 79-87.

Chen, Nai-Fu, Richard Roll and Stephen Ross, 1986, "Economic Forces and the Stock Market." Journal of
Business, 59, 3, 383-404.

Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber and M. Padberg, 1976, "Simple Rules for Optimal Portfolio Selection."
Journal of Finance, 31, 5, 1341-1357.

Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber and Thomas J. Urich, 1978, “Are Betas Best?”, Journal of Finance, 33,
5, 1375-1384.

Fishburn, Peter C., 1977, “Mean-Risk Analysis with Risk Associated with Below-Target Returns.”
American Economic Review, 67, 2, 116-126.

Harlow, W.V., 1991, "Asset Allocation in a Downside Risk Framework." Financial Analysts Journal, 47,
September/October, 28-40.

Hastings, N.A.J. and J.B. Peacock, 1975, Statistical Distributions: A Handbook for Students and
Practitioners, Halstead Press, New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Hogan, William W. and James M. Warren, 1972, “Computation of the efficient boundary in the E-S
Portfolio Selection Model.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 7, 4, 1881-1896.

Hunt, Lacy H., 1976, Dynamics of Forecasting Financial Cycles: Theory, Technique and Implementation,
JAI Press, Greenwich, CT.

Hunt, Lacy H., 1987, A Time to be Rich, Rawson Associates, Macmillan, New York, NY.

Liano, Kartono, 1992, "Macroeconomic Events and Seasonality of Risk and Returns," Applied Financial
Economics, 2, 4, 205-210.

Liano, Kartono, and Benton E. Gup, 1989, "The Day-of-the-Week Effect in Stock Returns," Financial
Analyst Journal, 45, 4, 74-77.

Liano, Kartono, Gow-Cheng Huang and Benton E. Gup, 1993, "A Twist on the Monday Effect in Stock
Returns: A Note," Journal of Economics and Business, 45, 1, 61-67.

background image

17

Markowitz, Harry M. 1991, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, Second Edition,
Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, MA.

Moore, Geoffrey H., 1983, Business Cycles, Inflation and Forecasting, NBER Research Studies in
Business Cycles, No. 24, Ballinger Publishing, Cambridge, MA.

Murphy, Roy E., 1965, Adaptive Processes in Economic Systems. New York: Academic Press.

Nawrocki, David N., 1983, "A Comparison of Risk Measures When Used in a Simple Portfolio Selection
Heuristic." Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 10, 2, 183-194.

Nawrocki, David N., 1984, “Entropy, Bifurcation and Dynamic Market Disequilibrium.” The Financial
Review, 19, 2, 266-284.

Nawrocki, David N., 1990, "Tailoring Asset Allocation to the Individual Investor," International Review
of Economics and Business, 37, 10-11, 183-194.

Nawrocki, David N., 1995, "R/S Analysis and Long Term Dependence in Stock Market Indices."
Managerial Finance, 21, 7, 78-91.

Peters, Edgar E., 1991, Chaos and Order in the Capital Markets, New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Peters, Edgar E., 1994, Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics,
New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Shannon, C.E. and W. Weaver, 1948, The Mathematical Theory of Communications, Urbana, IL:
University of Illinois.

Sharpe, William F., 1967, "A Linear Programming Algorithm for Mutual Fund Portfolio Selection."
Management Science, 14, 3, 499-510.

Stovall, Sam, 1996, Standard and Poors Guide to Sector Investing, New York: McGraw-Hill.

Vaga, Tonis, 1990, "The Coherent Market Hypothesis." Financial Analysts Journal, 46, 6, 36-49.

Vaga, Tonis, 1994, Profiting From Chaos, McGraw Hill, New York, NY.

background image

18

Table 1 - Geometrically Linked Annualized Returns and Monthly SemiDeviations for
26 Years (1969-1994) for Various Asset Classes

-----------------------------------------------------------------

1969 to 1969 to 1974 to 1983 to
1994 1973 1982 1994
Asset Classes Total Period Vietnam Oil Crisis Recovery
-----------------------------------------------------------------
S&P 500 Stocks 10.17 -2.36 13.73 14.41
(3.00) (3.68) (2.73) (2.81)
Mid-Cap Stocks 11.73 -6.56 22.18 14.67
(3.55) (4.65) (3.18) (3.15)
Small-Cap Stocks 11.53 -10.50 28.29 12.71
(4.13) (5.29) (3.77) (3.70)
LB LT Govt. 7.65 0.04 7.72 11.62
(1.78) (0.98) (2.24) (1.73)
LB G/C Intermediate 7.71 1.18 9.52 9.83
(0.78) (0.68) (1.12) (0.56)
Gold 9.15 25.03 14.08 -1.16
(3.37) (2.75) (4.18) (3.00)
90 Day T-Bill 7.28 6.22 9.04 6.57
(0.07) (0.11) (0.14) (0.02)
CPI - Consumer Prices 5.77 6.49 8.25 3.69
(0.22) (0.21) (0.26) (0.15)
CPI - New Cars 3.88 3.02 6.05 2.84
(0.61) (0.99) (0.62) (0.35)
CPI - Food & Beverages 5.46 7.80 6.82 3.44
(0.33) (0.36) (0.45) (0.23)
CPI - Fuel 6.41 8.98 13.82 0.81
(0.87) (0.30) (0.45) (1.13)
Median House Prices 6.79 7.46 8.37 5.41
(2.42) (2.53) (2.00) (2.59)

Data sources include Lehman Brothers bond indexes, CRSP stock
datasets, and CITIBASE/Fame/DRI economic database.

background image

19

Table 2 - Hunt's Phases of the General Economic Cycle
----------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 1 (EASEOFF) - Economy reaches a peak as defined by the NBER and real
GNP starts to decline. The decision rules that indicate the start of this
phase include: a 12 month percentage rate of change moving average for
industrial production turns negative, initial unemployment claims increase,
and nonfarm payrolls decline.

Phase 2 (PLUNGE) Real GNP declines as interest rates peak. The economy reaches
a trough as defined by the NBER. The decision rules that indicate the
start of this phase include: a 12 month rate of change moving average for
federal funds rates turns negative and a 6 month rate of change moving
average for the real monetary base turns positive.

Phase 3 (REVIVAL 1 or Early Revival) - Real GNP starts to increase.
The decision rules that indicate the start of this phase include: a 12 month
percentage rate of change for industrial production levels off towards a zero
percent change, initial unemployment claims decrease, and nonfarm payrolls
increase.

Phase 4 (REVIVAL 2 or Late Revival) - Real GNP recovers from the recession
The decision rules that indicate the start of this phase include: a 12 month
percentage rate of change for industrial production becomes positive and
nonfarm payrolls increase at a higher rate.

Phase 5 (ACCELERATE) - The economy continues to grow at a high rate prompting
the Federal Reserve to tighten credit, resulting in decreased consumer
spending while business investment continues to increase. The decision rules
that indicate the start of this phase include: a 6 month rate of change in
consumer prices turns positive, a 12 month rate of change in federal funds
rates turns positive, a 6 month rate of change moving average for the real
monetary base turns negative, and nonfarm payrolls increase at an even
higher rate.

Reference: Hunt(1976), The decision rules were determined using Hunt's
methodology with data from 1970 to 1986.

background image

20

Table 3 - Dates of the US Business Cycle, Percentage Changes and Correlation
Coefficients for Macroeconomic Variables During Different Phases of
Business Cycle. (Monthly Data - January 1970 to December 1986)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Easeoff(1) Plunge(2) Revival 1(3) Revival 2(4) Accelerate(5)
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Dates 12/69-4/70P 5/70-12/70T 1/71-5/71 6/71-10/72 11/72-3/73
4/73-9/74P 10/74-5/75T 6/75-12/75 1/72-2/77 3/77-3/79
4/79-4/80P 5/80-7/80T 8/80-12/80 1/81-8/81
9/81-10/81P 11/81-10/82 11/82-4/83T 5/83-10/83 11/83-4/84
5/84-10/84 11/84-8/86 9/86-12/86
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Annualized Percent Changes
S&P -14.59 24.74 22.33 6.34 -0.99
IP -0.92 -5.20 8.96 8.82 7.26
FYFF 22.49 -47.77 35.32 2.69 46.71
FYFF(-12) 44.68 -21.72 -36.61 -7.69 28.12
FMBASE -3.28 3.50 3.62 2.33 1.78
FMBASE(-6) -6.08 5.17 9.42 8.21 6.47
FMFBA -2.47 2.81 3.41 2.08 1.73
FM1DQ -4.95 4.54 2.91 3.18 0.14
LPNAG 1.85 -0.75 2.23 3.05 5.06
LUINC 60.37 7.27 -36.15 -6.05 -12.65
CPI 10.51 4.28 5.54 5.14 6.85
CPI-Energy 23.68 -2.12 4.21 5.77 7.12
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Correlations
S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP S&P IP
S&P 1.00 .07 1.00 -.03 1.00 -.15 1.00 .34* 1.00 .20
IP .07 1.00 -.03 1.00 -.15 1.00 .34* 1.00 .20 1.00
FYFF -.07 .34* -.22* .42* -.14 .28* -.19* -.13 -.20 .01
FYFF(-12) -.03 .08 -.15 -.04 .01 .19 -.25* -.11 -.05 -.07
FMBASE .07 .22* -.05 .24* .24 -.41* .11 .36* -.23* -.17
FMBASE(-6) .06 .38* -.12 .50* .22 -.23 .02 .23* -.19 .03
FMFBA .17 .07 .06 .31* .25 -.41* .26* .36* .01 -.06
FM1DQ .24* .02 .16 .18* .30* -.18 .20* .05 .16 -.07
LPNAG .10 .51* .06 .76* -.43* .51* .46* .43* .03 .66*
LUINC -.30* -.63* .23* -.46* -.22 .31* -.32* -.34* -.13 -.20
CPI -.08 -.03 -.03 -.33* -.05 .56* -.25* -.31* .14 .03
CPI-Energy .11 -.10 .03 -.15 -.21 .05 -.04 -.17 .03 -.03
df 43 53 23 49 35
* indicates significance at 10%
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Citibase/Fame/DRI access codes are used to represent the various macroeconomic
variables. All time series are monthly and seasonally adjusted with the
exception of the S&P. All data are percentage changes and are nominal amounts
except where noted.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P S&P 500 Composite Index FMFBA Real Monetary Base (Fed)
IP Industrial Production FM1DQ Real M1 Money Supply
FYFF Federal Funds Rate of Change LPNAG Non-Farm Payroll
FYFF(-12) Fed Funds 12 Mo. Rate of Change LUINC Initial Unemployment
FMBASE Real Monetary Base (St.Louis Fed) CPI Consumer Price Index
FMBASE(-6) Real Monetary Base - 6 Mo. ROC CPI-Energy Consumer Energy Prices
A NBER defined peak (P) or trough (T) appeared during this period.

background image

21

Table 4 - Characteristics of Vaga's Different Types of Market Behavior
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Market
Behavior Skewness Kurtosis Return Risk Mode
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Chaotic Significant Leptokurtic Low High Bimodal
Skewness

Coherent Significant Leptokurtic High Low Unimodal
Negative
Skewness

Transition Symmetric Platykurtic Varying Varying Unimodal

Random Walk Symmetric Mesokurtic Average Average Unimodal
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Source: Vaga[1990]

Leptokurtic - Peaked probability distribution
Platykurtic - Flat probability distribution
Mesokurtic - Normal distribution
---------------------------------------------------------------------

background image

22

Table 5 - 15 Industries Selected by Ranking by R/LPM Ratio for the Five Phases of the
Economic Cycle (1970-1986). All R/LPM Ratios are Positive.
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Easeoff Phase 1 Plunge Phase 2 Revival 1 Phase 3
---------------------------------------------------------------------
GOLD MINING UTILITY STOCKS ELECTRIC POWER
OIL-GAS DRILLING CONSUMER GOODS FOODS
TOBACCO FOODS TEXTILE-APPAREL MFRS
CHEM-SPECIALTY BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK PAPER & FOREST PRODUCTS
CHEM-DIVERSIFIED TOBACCO CONTAINERS-PAPER
OIL-DOMESTIC PUBLISHING PUBLISHING
HOUSEWARES DRUGS PUBLISHING-NEWSPAPERS
CONTAINERS-METAL MEDICAL PRODUCTS CHEMICALS
ALUMINUM HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS CHEMICALS-DIVERSIFIED
COMMUN.EQUIP.MFR COSMETICS OIL-INTERNATIONAL
ELECTRONICS-DEFENSE OIL-INTERNATIONAL SHOES
AEROSPACE/DEFENSE SHOES CONTAINERS-METAL&GLASS
RAILROADS HOUSEHOLD FURNISHINGS STEEL
TRANSPORTATION-MISC AUTO PARTS-AFTERMKT POLLUTION CONTROL
TELEPHONE MANUFACTURED HOUSING HOUSEHOLD FURN&APPL
-------------------------------------------------------------------

Revival 2 Phase 4 Accelerate Phase 5
-------------------------------------------------------------------
ELECTRIC POWER CAPITAL GOODS
OIL&GAS DRILLING GOLD MINING
BEVERAGES-ALCOHOLIC MACHINE TOOLS
BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK OILWELL EQUIP&SERVICE
PUBLISHING-NEWSPAPERS OIL&GAS DRILLING
HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS BEVERAGES-SOFT DRINK
OILWELL EQUIP&SERVICE TOBACCO
MACHINE TOOLS CONTAINERS-PAPER
POLLUTION CONTROL DRUGS
ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTS
HOUSEHOLD FURN&APPL COSMETICS
COMM. EQUIP MFR CHEMICALS-DIVERSIFIED
ELECTRONICS-DEFENSE OIL-DOMESTIC
AUTOMOBILES OIL-INTERNATIONAL
AUTO PARTS-AFTER MKT COMPUTER SYSTEMS
-------------------------------------------------------------------

background image

23

Table 6 - Historic Performance of R/LPM Heuristic, Covariance Optimization and
Cosemivariance Optimization (1958-1987)
--------------------------------------------------------------------
Revision Best LPM R/LPM Covariance Cosemivariance
Period Degree Risk-Return Risk-Return Risk-Return
--------------------------------------------------------------------
3 1.2 0.2287 0.1536 0.1505
6 1.0 0.2430 0.1636 0.1736
12 1.6 0.2363 0.1494 0.1541
24 1.4 0.2221 0.1383 0.1636
36 2.8 0.2201 0.1230 0.1744
48 4.6 0.2467 0.0842 0.1490

--------------------------------------------------------------------

Revision Period indicates that the portfolios were revised every 3,
6, 12, 24, 36, and 48 months. Transaction costs of 1% were
assessed during each revision.

Best LPM Degree indicates the LPM degree that provided the best risk-
return performance for the particular revision strategy.

Risk-Return is measured using the reward to semivariability ratio
(R/SV).
--------------------------------------------------------------------

background image

24

Table 7 - Quarterly Return Values (In Per Cent) for the Period 3/4/1988 to
2/10/1995 Using Portfolios Selected According to Industry and Phase of
Economic Cycle. 20 Asset Portfolios Selected Using the R/LPM Heuristic
and a Historic 104 Week Period.
-------------------------------------------------------------------
R/LPM
Per Begin EndDate S&P500 20 Asset Skew Kurt Phase TSerCor
-------------------------------------------------------------------
1 880304 880513 -2.16 5.69 -1.2452* 6.3045 5 1.2575
2 880520 880819 1.35 4.92 -1.2904* 6.4832 5 1.4942*
3 880826 881111 2.95 2.69 -1.2253* 6.4769 5 1.2928*
4 881118 890217 10.77 8.78 -1.1482* 6.6135 1 1.2766
5 890224 890512 5.75 16.71 -1.2241* 6.9247 1 1.1697
6 890519 890818 10.26 18.68 -1.3078* 7.2141 1 1.0979
7 890825 891110 -2.00 5.55 -1.3361* 7.3787 1 1.0071
8 891117 900216 -1.88 -5.42 -.4724* 4.2490 2 -2.7017*
9 900223 900511 5.80 13.78 -.7213* 4.4377 2 -2.8019*
10 900518 900817 -6.87 -1.48 -.6377* 4.3465 2 -2.1705* P
11 900824 901109 -4.30 -4.99 -.7462* 4.0964 2 -1.7145*
12 901116 910215 17.63 21.73 -.6324* 3.6199 2 -2.3073*
13 910222 910510 1.81 2.84 -.3729 3.3695 2 -1.4940* T
14 910517 910802 3.04 6.88 -.3289 3.4657 3 -1.7066*
15 910809 911108 1.48 11.80 -.2441 3.4611 3 -1.6667*
16 911115 920214 4.99 5.53 .0863 2.7983 4 -.6462
17 920221 920508 .87 6.92 .2442 2.7658 4 -.1229
18 920515 920807 .68 8.50 .2675 3.0080 4 -.2968
19 920814 921106 -.31 3.85 .3047 3.2201 4 -.8695
20 921113 930219 3.99 15.74 .6342* 3.4456 4 .1902
21 930226 930507 1.86 2.48 .3824 3.1078 4 -.5334
22 930514 930806 1.44 5.31 .3478 3.1640 4 -.8014
23 930813 931105 2.43 -3.99 .4362 3.6096 4 -.5644
24 931112 940218 1.77 2.87 .4160 3.9379 4 -.3526
25 940218 940506 -4.25 -5.82 -.0480 2.9348 5 -2.3499*
26 940513 940812 3.16 -2.22 -.2545 3.3402 5 -1.3995*
27 940819 941111 .09 4.10 -.6528* 3.8141 5 -1.1435
28 941118 950210 4.13 3.36 -.5194* 3.5421 5 -2.3490*
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Frequency(R20 > Rm) 20
Binomial Probability 0.0188 (n=28 p=0.5)
* - indicates statistical significance for 10% level of significance.
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Aggregate Statistic
S&P 500 R/LPM 20 Asset
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Weekly Geometric Mean 0.1673% 0.3855%
Standard Deviation 1.6917 2.2574
Reward/Variability (R/V) 0.0377 0.1249
Semideviation 1.1958 1.5033
Reward/Semideviation (R/SV) 0.1467 0.2645
Annualized Return 9.0805 22.1486
-------------------------------------------------------------------
Per - Period Number
P and T are NBER Defined Peaks and Troughs
TSerCor - T-statistic for one week lag serial correlation on S&P500
Skew - Skewness
Kurt - Kurtosis
R20 - 20 Asset R/LPM Portfolio
Rm - S&P 500 Return

background image

25

Table 8 - Performance Results for the Period March 3, 1988 to February 10, 1995
for Total Period and Different Phases
__________________________________________________________________
Total Period - Number of Observations: 363 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 9.08% 1.69% 1.20% .1467 -0.19* 4.02 -2.85*
No Indust 18.56 2.51 1.63 .2013 -0.12 3.83 -0.56
Industry 22.15 2.26 1.50 .2645#-0.33* 4.57 -2.35*
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 1 - Number of Observations: 47 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 26.69% 1.93% 1.40% .3267 -1.49* 6.41 -3.20* Coherent
No Indust 39.63 2.21 1.50 .4290 -1.35* 5.65 -0.22
Industry 57.79 2.18 1.29 .6933#-0.72* 3.88 -1.99*
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 2 - Number of Observations: 79 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 8.61% 2.13% 1.39% .1143 0.08 2.63 -0.19 Random
No Indust 19.36 2.88 1.86 .1829 -0.09 3.10 -0.20
Industry 17.83 2.65 1.72 .1837#-0.19 3.90 -0.71
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 3 - Number of Observations: 26 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 -7.63% 1.53% 1.13% -.1303 0.14 2.01 -0.62 Transition
No Indust 37.12 2.68 1.46 .4173# 0.30 3.20 -0.53
Indust 12.86 2.25 1.32 .1770 0.49 2.85 -0.21
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 4 - Number of Observations: 113 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 11.87% 1.24% 0.73% .2968 0.45* 4.32 -0.93 Coherent
No Indust 25.71 2.43 1.42 .3096 0.21 4.28 -0.34
Indust 27.35 1.78 1.04 .4481#-0.13 3.92 -0.38
------------------------------------------------------------------
Phase 5 - Number of Observations: 98 SerCor
Portfolio AnnRet StdDev SemiDev R/SV Skew Kurt T-Test Vaga
-------------------------------------------------------------------
S&P500 3.38% 1.69% 1.18% .0540 -0.08 3.61 -1.70* Chaotic
No Indust -1.96 2.36 1.75 -.0216 -0.26 3.47 -0.34
Indust 8.27 2.45 1.73 .0881#-0.46* 4.95 -1.93*
-------------------------------------------------------------------
# - Indicates best risk-return performance.
* - Indicates statistical significance for 10% level of significance.
AnnRet - Annualized return.
StdDev - Monthly standard deviation in per cent.
SemiDev - Monthly semideviation (square root of semivariance).
R/V - Reward to variability ratio (using standard deviation).
R/SV - Reward to semivariability ratio (using semideviation).
Skew - Skewness of portfolio returns.
Kurt - Kurtosis of portfolio returns.
T-Test - T-test of 104 week serial correlations of the S&P 500.


Wyszukiwarka

Podobne podstrony:
Marijuana is one of the most discussed and controversial topics around the world
Preliminary Analysis of the Botany, Zoology, and Mineralogy of the Voynich Manuscript
Orzeczenia, dyrektywa 200438, DIRECTIVE 2004/58/EC OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of
[Mises org]Mises,Ludwig von The Causes of The Economic Crisis And Other Essays Before And Aft
Chapter 15 Diseases of the Urinary Tract and Kidney
Legg Calve Perthes disease The prognostic significance of the subchondral fracture and a two group c
Isabelle Rousset A Behind the Scenes Report on the Making of the Show Visuals and Delivery Systems
Racism, Racial Discrimination, Xenophobia and Related Forms of Intolerance, Follow up and Implementa
Soliwoda, Katarzyna i inni The influence of the chain length and the functional group steric access
Geoffrey de Villehardouin Memoirs or Chronicle of The Fourth Crusade and The Conquest of Constantin
Comparative Analyses of the Bacterial Microbiota of the Human Nostril and Oropharynx
0415216451 Routledge Naturalization of the Soul Self and Personal Identity in the Eighteenth Century
Death and return of the author criticism and subjectivity in barthes foucault and derrida
Racism, Racial Discrimination, Xenophobia and Related Forms of Intolerance, Follow up and Implementa
Dr Who Target 107 The Mark of the Rani # Pip and Jane Baker
Rodrigues & Vaz SUBLUMINAL AND SUPERLUMINAL SOLUTIONS IN VACUUM OF THE MAXWELL EQUATIONS AND THE MA
The Book of The Secret Word And The Higher Way To Fortune Arthur Edward Waite
Alfta Reginleif Religious Practices of the Pre Christian and Viking Age (2002)

więcej podobnych podstron