Understanding Business Group Performance in an
Emerging Economy: Acquiring Resources and
Capabilities in Order to Prosper*
Daphne Yiu, Garry D. Bruton and Yuan Lu
Chinese University of Hong Kong; Texas Christian University; Chinese University of Hong Kong
The prevalent organizational form in most emerging markets is business
groups. These groups have typically been viewed through a transaction cost
economics perspective where they are perceived as responses to inefficiencies in the
market. However, the evidence to date on what generates a positive business group-
performance relationship in such environments is not well understood. This study
expands the understanding of business groups by employing the resource-based and
institutional theoretical perspectives to examine how groups acquire resources and
capabilities to prosper. The empirical evidence is based on over 224 business groups
in the emerging economy context of China and shows that most of the endowed
government resources do not help business groups to create a competitive edge.
Instead, those business groups with strategic actions to develop a unique portfolio of
market-oriented resources and capabilities are most likely to prosper. The results
provide critical insights on the relationship between the initiation of institutional
transformation and the desired outcome to be realized by organizational
transformation, thus enriching our understanding of institutions and strategic choices
facilitated or constrained by organizational resources in emerging economies.
INTRODUCTION
A business group is a collection of legally independent firms that are bound by
economic (such as ownership, financial, and commercial) and social (such as family,
kinship, and friendship) ties. This unique organizational form has significant eco-
nomic impact on emerging economies. For example, 40 per cent of Korea’s total
output was contributed by the top 30 business groups (Chang and Hong, 2000).
In China, business groups contributed close to 60 per cent of the nation’s indus-
trial output (China Economic Yearbook, 2000; China Statistical Yearbook, 2000). Despite
Journal of Management Studies 42:1 January 2005
0022-2380
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ ,
UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
Address for reprints: Daphne Yiu, Department of Management, Chinese University of Hong Kong,
Shatin, N. T., Hong Kong (dyiu@cuhk.edu.hk).
their significant contribution to the wealth of emerging economies, to date the
understanding of business groups has remained insufficient. Prior researchers have
examined business groups describing their founding (Keister, 1998), or the level of
diversification of business group firms in emerging economies (Khanna and
Palepu, 2000). However, researchers have largely treated business groups as a
unified set of businesses. The different factors that impact how business groups
seek to create value have been ignored.
In part, this absence of examination is due to the prior reliance on institutional
economics, in particular transaction cost economics, as the key theoretical per-
spective. From an economics perspective, business groups substitute for imperfect
market institutions in the emerging economies (Caves and Uekusa, 1976; Chang
and Choi, 1988; Khanna and Palepu, 1997, 2000; Wright et al., 2005; Leff, 1978).
Such a theoretical underpinning largely assumes that there is a uniform answer
on strategic choices made by business groups as they seek to lower transaction
costs. The limits imposed by a narrow theoretical lens such as transaction cost
theory has led to other theoretical lens to emerge. The economic sociology per-
spective argues that resource scarcity in emerging economies forces organizations
to restrict activity to certain limited functions, which then requires exchange with
other organizations (Cook, 1977). As such, firms form into business groups through
repeated transactions and by factors such as geographic region, political party, eth-
nicity, kinship, or religion (Granovetter, 1994). The prevalent growth of business
groups in late economic development formed another view of business groups as
a way for the state to support, or secure support from, entrepreneurs (Amsden,
1989). Chang and Hong (2000) and Guillén (2000) examined business groups from
a resource based view, arguing that business groups add value to member firms by
pooling and distributing heterogeneous resources through related and unrelated
diversification. Taking an evolutionary perspective, recent studies have traced the
evolution of business groups in regard to pattern of diversification and organiza-
tional structure over time (Kim et al., 2004; Kock and Guillén, 2001).
While there have been a variety of theoretical perspectives of business groups,
institutional theory appears to be a relevant but under utilized theoretical lens for
the study of emerging economies, as does resource-based theory (Hoskisson et al.,
2000). Peng (2000a) advocated that research on emerging economies is conducive
for integration of institutional and resource-based theories. The use of other the-
oretical underpinnings for the examination of business groups has brought unique
insights, but there has been limited prior effort to examine these two theoretical
lenses together. Thus, we do not disagree with the transaction economics per-
spective that business groups serve to fill the institutional voids in emerging
economies and reduce transaction costs for member firms in the groups. However,
we believe a richer theoretical understanding that relates the development of firm’s
resource portfolio and the institutional transition process of the emerging
economies is needed.
184
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
In this study, we propose that the value-creating potential of a business group
is largely dependent on how business groups are able to acquire resources and gen-
erate capabilities necessary to prosper. Nonetheless, given the institutional reality
that the firms in transition economies are embedded in the old central controlled
economy, the value-creating potential of the business group will be constrained by
the endowed resources of that group. By integrating a resource-based view with
the institutional perspective, we argue that the values created by business groups
vary depending on the resources and capabilities the groups are able to obtain.
Specific research questions raised include: What is the role of the business group,
as an organizational form, in emerging economies undergoing institutional tran-
sition? And what factors account for the variations in business group performance?
By addressing these issues, we hope to provide a better understanding of busi-
ness groups in emerging economies. In particular, we offer several fresh insights
including a new perspective that views business groups as an instrument, instead
of a product, of institutional transition. Second, unlike past studies on business
groups that are anchored at the member firm level, this study analyses business
groups as wholes. Third, the study has captured the unique resource profile of
organizations at a stage of institutional transition, thus providing a deeper under-
standing on the complex structural reconfiguration process. Fourth, the empirical
evidence offers implications to managers and policy makers that business groups
can proactively seek to enhance their performance by developing a unique port-
folio through various strategic means.
To build this understanding, the manuscript will first provide the theoretical
foundations for the study from the institutional theory and resource-based per-
spectives. Next, our hypotheses are examined by both survey and archival data
from the largest 224 business groups in China. The manuscript concludes with a
discussion of the implications of the findings for the study of business groups and
businesses in emerging economies.
LITERATURE REVIEW AND THEORETICAL FOUNDATION
Literature Review on Business Group Performance
Empirical evidence about the beneficial effects of business groups on economic
development via their effects on the member firm performance has remained
mixed (Aoki, 1982; Caves and Uekusa, 1976; Chang and Choi, 1988; Khanna and
Palepu, 2000; Leff, 1978; Stark, 1996). Some studies have shown that business
groups helped to create positive effects for member firms’ performance. For
example, Chang and Choi (1988) empirically showed that business groups with a
multidivisional structure that reduces transaction costs and provides economies of
scale and scope, for example, the Korean chaebols, result in superior performance.
Using panel data from 1988 to 1990 on China’s business groups, Keister (1998)
Business Group Performance
185
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
found that the presence and predominance of interlocking directorates and finance
companies in business groups improved the financial performance and productiv-
ity of member firms, and more centralized groups performed better than others.
Perotti and Gelfer (2001) also provided evidence that group members have higher
values of Tobin’s q than otherwise comparable independent firms in Russia.
On the other hand, there is also evidence that business groups result in a
negative impact on firm performance. Caves and Uekusa (1976) and Nakatani
(1984) both found a negative relationship between group membership and firm
performance in the Japanese keiretsu. The negative results may be due to the fact
that ‘interest payments passing to the banks may be a conduit for group-derived
rents’ (Caves and Uekusa, 1976, p. 78). Outside of Japan, Khanna and Yafeh
(1999) supported the negative relationship between group membership and firm
performance. In half of the ten emerging economies in their sample (e.g. Brazil,
India, Korea, Taiwan, Thailand), the inter-temporal variance of firm profitabil-
ity, measured by the ratio of operating returns to assets, was lower for group affil-
iates than non-group affiliates. These empirical results suggest that there is, indeed,
a cost of affiliating with business groups.
The mixed empirical findings on group-performance indicate that richer theo-
retical examinations that investigate other variables are needed to understand what
impacts business group performance. We approach this examination with a strate-
gic perspective that such groups have the ability to make strategic choices that
will impact their performance. Thus, rather than treating business groups being
uniform sets of firms with given characteristics, we view business groups as col-
lections of resources. It is the ability of business groups to configure different types
of resources to fit the emerging competitive environment that contributes to their
success.
Business Groups: A Resource-Based Perspective
One of the unique characteristics of the institutional change in emerging
economies is the simultaneous operation of market mechanisms and the presence
of the remaining state governance mechanisms (Stark, 1996). Child (1993) high-
lighted this issue when he argued that the key factor that delineates a market-based
system from that of a hierarchical system that characterized central planning is
the importance of strategic context. The emerging strategic context in the new
institutional environment implies that a firm’s resource portfolio and capabilities
derived from it will impose significant impacts on its strategic competitiveness.
From the resource-based perspective, it has been argued that a firm’s competitive
advantage is derived from unique bundles of resources that are difficult for com-
petitors to duplicate – either through imitation or substitution (Barney, 1991).
There have been prior examinations of business groups from a resource-based
view. Conceptualizing business group as a portfolio of heterogeneous resources,
186
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Chang and Hong (2000) pointed out that member firms not only enjoy the natural
benefits resulting from a multidivisional structure, but they can also benefit from
internal business transactions for the purpose of cross-subsidization. Guillén (2000)
suggested that firms and entrepreneurs, by having access to business groups, could
accumulate an inimitable capability to combine domestic and foreign resources to
enter industries more quickly and cost-effectively in emerging economies. While
finding support for the resource-based view, these studies did not examine a rich
set of potential resources and capabilities that could be acquired in order to
prosper. Also, these studies have not looked into the endowed resource condition
of a business group.
The initial formation of business groups have typically been induced by the gov-
ernment where they are located as a tool of fostering economic development, not
only as a product of those economic efforts. To illustrate, Guillén (1997) pointed
out that the growth of Korean business groups (chaebols) was in line with the gov-
ernment’s industrial policy and export-led growth strategy. Literature suggests that
government involvement has been particularly pertinent in the formation of busi-
ness groups in most emerging economies: Pakistan (White, 1974), Latin America
(Strachan, 1976), Indonesia (Schwartz, 1992), Korea (Chang and Choi, 1988;
Guillén, 2000), and China (Keister, 1998; Peng, 2001). Building on the close linkage
between business groups and government, we conceptualize business groups as an
instrument to facilitate organizational transformation – corporatization and legiti-
mization – during the institutional transition process in emergent economies.
Building on this theoretical conceptualization, we propose that there are two
different sources of the potential resources and capabilities that a business group
could acquire. The first type is endowed resources, which has not been extensively
studied. Many business groups in emergent markets were formed from formerly
state-owned enterprises and government bureaus that are already endowed with
a pool of government resources when they were transformed into business groups.
As such, administrative and ownership history of business groups that results from
their status as former government enterprises impacts group development (Keister,
1998). Once the business groups are formed, they have autonomy in pursuing dif-
ferent strategies to acquire resources and develop market capabilities in order to
enhance their strategic competitiveness. We call this second type of resources
‘acquired/developed resources’. Which source of resources would have the great-
est impact on group performance is not clear from the prior research. Therefore,
our focus in this study is to examine how these two types of resources impose
heterogeneous effects on group performance.
Business Groups: China
A key aspect of the Economic Reform in China that has been generating this
nation’s growth is the establishment of business groups. Over the last 15 years
Business Group Performance
187
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
business groups in China have grown from being non-existent to a point where
they contribute approximately 60 per cent of the nation’s industrial output (China
Economic Yearbook, 2000; China Statistical Yearbook, 2000). Business groups serve as the
primary economic engine for the development of the national and local economies
in China (Keister, 1998; Nolan, 2001). The reason that business groups have been
used by the government as a tool of economic reform is that China has needed
to move from a hierarchical system that typifies central planning to a market-based
system (Child, 1993). The Chinese government knew that without making sys-
tematic choices in this transition it could end up with the chaos as reflected in the
Russian transition. Therefore, the nation needed an intermediary institution that
would facilitate the enterprise reform and, thereby, the economic transition. The
solution was the encouragement of business group formation that would facilitate
the movement towards the market based system.
Consistent with their use as transitional institutions, today business groups in
China commonly include both publicly traded and government owned firms in
their portfolio of affiliated firms. Illustrative of the complexity of business groups
in China is Desay, a business group founded in 1983 that includes 25 affiliated
firms. Some of the affiliated firms have publicly traded stock and some do not.
These various business units compete in ten industries including electronics, tele-
phone equipment, audio and visual products, construction materials, and real
estate, and employ approximately 11,000 employees. Some of these business units
were assigned to the business group while the parent firm itself invested in, and
took control of, other member firms within the group. In summary, the gradual
institutional transition of China provides a natural experiment for us to examine
how bundles of endowed and newly developed resources in a business group affect
the group’s performance.
HYPOTHESES
As noted before, resources for the business group can be endowed or
acquired/developed. Those resources that are endowed are present in the group
from its initial founding, while those resources that are acquired/created come
from the business group’s efforts to create or obtain the resources. Each source of
resources will be reviewed in turn.
Endowed Resources
Group age. From an evolutionary perspective, the history of a firm reflects a dis-
tinctive bundle of critical resource, organizational skills and capabilities that have
been accumulated over time, which in turn, exerts significant influence on a firm’s
choice of growth strategies and organizational structure (Nelson and Winter, 1982;
Penrose, 1959). Thus, the longer the history of the group the greater will be the
188
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
member firm’s embeddedness in its institutional environment. This embeddedness
is particularly important in an emergent market where organizational legitimacy
comes with age (Ahlstrom and Bruton, 2001). Increased legitimacy can lead to
increased performance since the high levels of volatility that characterize emer-
gent markets can result in firms that do not have such legitimacy receiving less
consideration by many key stakeholders. However, the institutional transition that
characterizes emergent markets means that legitimacy gained in the previous insti-
tutional period may no longer be valid as the institutional context moves to a
market focus. As such, the specific bundle of core resources that were developed
in the past may transform themselves into organizational inertia when the exter-
nal environment is changing (Hannan and Freeman, 1984). Business groups that
have been developed for a longer time will accumulate more obsolete resources
that inhibit a firm’s strategic flexibility. In an emerging economy like China, older
groups are more likely to have inherited an attitude conforming to the socialist
mentality, thus having a lower level of risk taking and profit focus. The reform of
most emergent markets has been in place close to 15 years and the institutional
transition from a hierarchy focus to a market focus is in full force. Thus, we expect
that business groups that are older will perform worse than those that have formed
more recently.
Hypothesis 1: The age of a business group is negatively related to the perfor-
mance of the business group.
Government ownership. Due to a lack of exit mechanisms for the full ownership in
the external capital market, governments usually retain a large proportion of own-
ership shares in business groups. However, government, as an owner, tends to place
more emphasis on allocating the financial resources for non-profit goals such as
provisions for social welfare and employment opportunities, than for shareholder
value and profit maximization (Boycko et al., 1995). For example, one of the great
issues facing China today is the unemployment among workers as the economy is
restructured. Thus, government entities commonly wish to maximize employment
in those businesses in which they have control in an effort to limit the potential
negative effects of unemployment on its citizens while other shareholders want to
maximize shareholder value and firm profits. This setting is illustrative of the
simultaneous operation of the emerging market mechanisms and the presence of
the remaining state governance mechanisms (Stark, 1996).
The expectation that governments want to maintain employment levels rather
than create new resources and capabilities in the firm is consistent with the evi-
dence found by Andrews and Dowling (1998). Their research found that post-
privatization gains did not materialize for firms where the government held sig-
nificant shares after the privatization process. The focus on goals other than share-
holder value and profit maximization is in contrast to what is expected of business
Business Group Performance
189
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
groups with a purer market orientation that come from limited or no government
ownership. As a result, it could be expected that higher levels of government stock
ownership leads to lower performance in the business group since resources will
not be spent on developing new resources or capabilities as the group’s business
environment changes.
Hypothesis 2: The share of government ownership held in a business group is
negatively related to the performance of the business group.
Top management background. One of the key resources, which competitors cannot
duplicate, is the human resources of the group, particularly the leadership. It is
the recognition of the value of human resources, particularly that of the individ-
ual that leads a business, that inspired the upper-echelons perspective of man-
agement (Finkelstein and Hambrick, 1990). The firm’s leadership, the theory
argues, pattern their strategic choices to match their view of the world, which in
turn determines firm performance (Hambrick and Mason, 1984).
Deciding whether and how to enact to the environment is determined by the
decision makers’ understanding of the situation and their motivation (Ocasio,
1997). When making such decisions in novel situations, decision makers apply the
repertoire of available issues and answers and relate areas of commonality with
past situations in the firm. Therefore, the background of the top management is
expected to significantly impact the strategic actions pursued and the resulting per-
formance of the business groups. During institutional upheavals, managers may
lack an understanding of what is needed to be successful since the environment
has changed and the transitioning environment is full of uncertainty (Roth and
Kostova, 2003). In the case of business groups, the top management of the group
often comes from the government unit that established the business group. Thus,
the pool of managers who previously worked in the government setting is lacking
the corporate mindsets and incentives to engage in market-oriented activities
and/or create the resources and capabilities for their changing environment. These
top managers may even lack the knowledge and skills necessary to employ cor-
rectly those resources and capabilities even if they are developed (Zahra et al.,
2000). As such, it could be expected that those business groups, where there is
greater dominance by the top management coming from government units, will
result in lower group performance.
Hypothesis 3: The number of top management who previously worked for the
government is negatively related to the performance of the business group.
Founding via transfer from industrial bureau. Group founding can have a similar
‘imprinting effect’ on the group’s approach to resource and capability develop-
ment (Stinchcombe, 1965). One of the focused efforts made by the government
190
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
to facilitate the institutional transition process is transforming state-owned enter-
prises or industrial bureaus into business groups with the goal of corporatization,
or market oriented firms like Western corporations.
There are two fundamentally different approaches used to form business groups
in China. The first occurred when a variety of firms, typically from a single gov-
ernment bureau, were transferred into a business group. In this setting member
firms that came together were often from very different industries with the only
consistent factor being the bureau that controlled them. In this setting, which
member was dominant typically was not clear. Instead, it was the founding bureau
that was the dominant power in the arrangement. As a result there could be a lack
of clear strategic direction, and in turn, a lack of clear focus on which resources
and capabilities to develop. The other means by which business groups are created
occurred when there was one dominant firm as the core of the business group.
This firm was typically a large firm, which other firms were assigned. A single firm
that is the foundation for the business group results in that firm having the
dominant role in deciding the strategic direction of the group.
There is relative greater difficulty in choosing, and then reconfiguring strategic
resources and capabilities, in a situation where the business group was founded by
transfers from government industrial bureaus. This is due to the fact that the split
leadership and highly unrelated diversification of the resulting group makes clear
strategic decision making and coordination more difficult. Also, such a ‘forced mar-
riage’ of firms into the business group may suggest a non-economic rationale for
resource combinations, resulting in a heavy social and financial burden on the
groups. This leads to the following hypothesis.
Hypothesis 4: Business groups that originated by transfers of businesses from gov-
ernment industrial bureaus will have lower performance.
Acquired/Developed Resources
Acquisition strategy. With the market being liberalized and developed, business
groups can act in a market fashion by identifying potential firms for the group and
pursing mergers and acquisitions of those firms. Alternatively, a business group
can found the desired businesses in a greenfield fashion where the desired firms
are created entrepreneurially by the business group themselves. Acquisition is the
quickest means for firms to acquire resources and capabilities available in the
market. Also, compared to groups that are transferred from government industrial
bureaus, acquisitions are likely to result in fewer integration difficulties and greater
synergies since acquisitions are undertaken voluntarily, and the business group is
clearly in a controlling position in selecting its member firms strategically.
Therefore, it is expected that acquisition strategy has a positive effect on group
performance.
Business Group Performance
191
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Hypothesis 5: Business groups that pursue more acquisitions will have higher
performance.
Internal capability development. According to Peng (2003), the capability needs of a
firm to have a competitive advantage will differ over the period of institutional
transition since the strategy choices and organizational constraints will vary as the
institutions change. The need for strategic fit for organizational success would indi-
cate that an organization that does not appreciate this need for changes as the
institutions change will eventually find itself obsolete (Zajac et al., 2000). One of
the advantages given to business groups is support from the government (Keister,
2000), which can initially be a source of success for business groups in emerging
economies. However, as the economy moves towards a market-based economy,
more transparent rules will be introduced, and the normative and cognitive pres-
sures for market-based competition given by start-up firms and foreign firms in
domestic and international markets will also increase (Peng, 2003). The result of
these changes is a significantly changed environment in which the strategic choices
and organizational constraints have changed. A business group that is relying on
institutional support by the government may find that it no longer fits with its new
environment.
Organizational change is typically very difficult for all organizations. This situa-
tion is accented in environments such as emergent economies where change occurs
in a very short period and the firms that relied on governmental support often
have dated physical equipment and uncompetitive product portfolio (Kornai,
1980). As a result, it could be expected that the better the fit the incumbent firms
have with the pre-transition institutional context, the more difficult it is for them
to successfully transform themselves (Peng, 2003) and reconfigure their resource
portfolio (Uhlenbruck et al., 2003). In contrast, those firms that did not rely on
government support, but instead focused on the development of market based
capabilities would be expected to prosper as the institutional transition proceeds.
Therefore, we propose that business groups that are able to develop strengths
in market-based capabilities will sustain competitiveness in the new environment.
These capabilities include technological capabilities to enhance efficiency and
continuous product development. Additionally, marketing capabilities that help
protect domestic firms in an emerging economy against entry by foreign firms will
also be critical (Hoskisson et al., 2000).
Hypothesis 6: Business groups that engage in more internal capability develop-
ment will have higher performance.
International diversification. Even when a business group acquires or develops
resources internally, sustainable competitive advantages may still not be guaran-
teed due to the fact that the strategic factor markets are, as yet, underdeveloped
192
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
in emerging economies. To create a bundle of unique resources and capabilities,
business groups may need to acquire resources outside their domestic boundary.
Makino et al. (2002) empirically supported that firms from less developed coun-
tries pursued strategic asset-seeking foreign direct investment with the intent to
acquire technology-based resources and skills in countries that are superior, or not
available in their home countries, will perform best. The international diversifica-
tion strategy allows firms to develop capabilities that assist them to compete more
successfully both internationally and domestically. Kobrin (1991) pointed out that
international diversification allows firms to get access to more diverse resources for
the development of innovation capabilities which is conducive to sustain com-
petitive advantages. This view is consistent with Hitt et al. (1997) who argued that
the complementarities between product diversification and international diversifi-
cation help a firm achieve economies of scale and scope to degrees unavailable
from either form of diversification alone. Given the diversified nature of business
groups, it is expected that international diversification leads to greater group
performance.
Hypothesis 7: Business groups that pursue more international diversification will
have higher performance.
METHODOLOGY
Sample and Data
Since there is a lack of consensus of what constitutes business groups in different
nations of the world, a single-country study appears to be a sensible first step to
understanding the more general issue of the business group’s nature worldwide
(Khanna and Rivkin, 2000). In this study, China was chosen as the empirical
setting. According to the official definition by the Chinese government, a business
group consists of legally independent entities that are partly or wholly owned by
a parent firm and registered as affiliated firms of that parent firm. One of the
biggest challenges of conducting empirical studies in China is data availability and
data validity. As such, we collected data with the help of China’s National Statis-
tics Bureau (CNSB) that is comparable to the Securities and Exchange Commis-
sion in the United States. Firms in China report a variety of information to the
CNSB annually and so participation and accuracy of the information provided by
the business group to the CNSB is required.
The accounting and financial information of this study, including the dependent
variable, is gathered from the official studies conducted by the CNSB annually. In
addition to this, we conducted two surveys which are independent of the CNSB’s
annual data collection efforts mentioned above. The archival survey data includes
mainly business group demographic variables such as the group characteristics and
Business Group Performance
193
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
degree of diversification. The chief accountants of the business groups reported
this data. The perceptual survey data concern qualitative evaluation of topics by
the chief executives in the sample business groups. The use of data from different
surveys filled out by different individuals lessened the possibility the common
method variance problem and reduced potential respondents’ bias. To further
ensure that common method variance did not pose significant inflation on the
results, we conducted Harman’s one-factor test as suggested by Podsakoff and
Organ (1986). The factor analysis showed that no single factor accounted for the
majority of the covariance in the independent and dependent variables.
In addition, the questionnaires were translated and back translated to eliminate
measurement errors due to language differences. Also, before launching the large-
scale distribution of the survey, a pilot study in which questionnaires tested by a
group of Chinese managers was conducted. Finally, during the full-scale data col-
lection, the local branches of the CNSB were in charge of distributing and col-
lecting the survey data while the Beijing headquarters was in charge of auditing
the data collection process and conducting follow-up phone interviews to validate
the information reported by the business groups. The surveys were distributed in
December 1998 and collected by February 1999.
We selected the largest 250 business groups in our study. The larger-sized busi-
ness groups are selected because they are most likely the engines for economic
growth while having greater government involvement according to Chinese gov-
ernment policy of ‘grasping the big enterprises and letting go of smaller ones’.
Also, larger-sized business groups are likely to have member firms that are restruc-
tured state-owned enterprises. To allow for effects of our independent variables to
be evident, we dropped business groups founded less than a year ago. After delet-
ing cases with missing information, the final sample size is 224.
Measures
Dependent Variable
Business group’s performance. The performance of business groups is measured by
return of assets (ROA) as of 1998. The performance measure is taken from a
separate source, the Business Group Enterprise Survey, which the business groups
are required to report to the State Statistics Bureau annually.
Independent Variables
Age of business group. The age of business group refers to the length of years since
the founding of the business group.
Government ownership. Government ownership is defined by the percentage of shares
owned by the government in the business groups.
194
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Number of previous government officials. This is measured by the total number of man-
agers, including CEO and divisional managers at the group headquarters, who
worked in the government before. This number is then weighted by number of
employees to indicate the level of intensity.
Founding dummy – transfer from industrial bureau. Taken from the perceptual survey,
this is a dummy variable such that a value of 1 indicates the business group was
transferred from a previous government industrial bureau and 0 indicates
otherwise.
Acquisition intensity. Acquisition intensity is measured by the percentage of acquisi-
tion expenditure on total sales.
Internal capability development. As mentioned previously, three types of firm capabil-
ities – technological, product, and marketing capabilities – are critical to meet the
emerging competitive environment in an emerging economy. Investment in equip-
ment serves as a vehicle for technological improvements, as new ideas would lie
fallow without the embodiment in new equipment. This is also important for
greater efficiency and capacity utilization rate. R&D expenditure is a major pre-
dictor of a firm’s involvement in innovative activities, which is a key factor for
sustaining competitiveness. Finally, marketing expenditures are important in an
emerging economy where distribution and market channels are not well estab-
lished. Therefore, the internal capability development scale consists of three items:
(1) investments on equipment; (2) R&D expenditures; and (3) marketing expendi-
tures. The three items were measured by a seven-point scale ranging from 1
(decreased) to 7 (increased) over the past three years in the perceptual survey. The
three items were loaded on the same factor in the factor analysis with factor load-
ings ranging from 0.80 to 0.91. The Cronbach’s alpha of the measure was 0.81.
International diversification. This is measured by the number of countries in which
the business groups have foreign direct investment. The scope measure is a
measure of the breadth or scope of international operations, and this is a better
measure of the amount of location-specific advantages resulted from international
diversification (Tallman and Li, 1996).
Control Variables
Four control variables are included. According to the resource-based literature
(Penrose, 1959), the growth and expansion decision of a firm is determined by
internal factors that define the constraints and opportunities placed on the firm.
Therefore, we include size and current ratio to control for slack resources avail-
able for firm’s acquisition, product innovations, and diversification (Chang, 1996;
Business Group Performance
195
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Chatterjee and Singh, 1999; Hitt et al., 1996; Schoenecker and Cooper, 1998).
Firm size is measured by the logarithms of number of employees. Current ratio
is measured by total assets divided by total equity. Besides, group diversification is
controlled. Group diversification is measured by the four-digit entropy measure.
The entropy measure is computed according to Palepu (1985):
where Pi stands for the percentage of a member firm’s sales revenue in i industry.
Finally, the context of an emerging economy is characterized by gradual market
liberation. That means, some industries are still fully protected by government
while others are gradually opened for market competition. As a result, industry
competitiveness is controlled for. We created an industry competitiveness index of
a business group, which indicates the extent of market competitiveness of the
industries where the member firms are located. This is computed as follows. First,
following the China Industry Development Report (1999), we measured the extent of
market competitiveness of the industry in which each of the member firms is
located. A value of 1 indicates that the industry is having state monopoly, a value
of 2 refers to an industry that is semi-opened, and 3 for industry that is fully
opened. Then, the industry competitiveness index of a business group is computed
by summing up the market competitiveness score of each member firm weighted
by its total sales.
RESULTS
Table I presents the means, standard deviations, and correlations of the variables
included in this study. We checked the variance inflation factors (VIFs) to assess if
multicollinearity is a problem and the results indicated that multicollinearity does
not pose a problem to our results. To mitigate the potential threat of heterokes-
dascity, we estimated the OLS regressions using Huber-White’s robust standard
error which has been previously used in extant research on business groups (Chang,
2003; Khanna and Palepu, 2000). To test our hypotheses, control variables were
first entered in Model 1, with independent variables regarding the sets of endowed
resources and developed resources inserted in Model 2 and Model 3 respectively.
Model 4 represents the full model. Finally, recent literature on product diversifi-
cation has highlighted that diversification is a choice variable that is endogenous
and self-selected (see Campa and Kedia, 2002 for details) and the endogeneity
issue may apply in the relationship between international diversification and per-
formance. To control for the endogeneity of the international diversification deci-
sion, we performed a two-step Heckman test and the results are shown in Model
5. Table II presents the regression results.
DT
Pi
Pi
i
i
N
=
Ê
Ë
ˆ
¯
=
=
Â
ln
1
1, 2, 3,
M
1
,
. . . ,
196
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Business Gr
oup P
erf
or
mance
197
© Blackw
ell Pub
lishing Ltd 2005
Table I. Descriptive statistics and correlations
Variables
Mean
S.D.
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
1. Performance: ROA
0.018
0.0349
2. Group age
5.370
3.559
-0.079
3. Top management
0.037
0.084
-0.080
0.029
background
4. Government 0.738
0.322
-0.300**
-0.223**
-0.069
ownership
5. Group transferred
0.170
0.376
-0.047
0.107
-0.055
-0.001
from govt bureau
6. Acquisition to
4.851
12.766
0.147*
-0.088
-0.067
-0.110
-0.144*
sales (%)
7. Internal capability
5.149
1.323
0.324**
-0.075
-0.138*
-0.077
-0.006
0.041
development
8. International 4.660
13.459
0.019
0.073
0.016
0.087
0.013
-0.084
-0.097
diversification
9. Log of employees
9.534
1.276
-0.140*
0.045
-0.487**
0.127
0.322**
-0.047
-0.087
0.164*
10. Current ratio
1.879
0.898
0.291**
-0.004
-0.086
-0.256**
-0.092
-0.006
0.128
-0.094
-0.046
11. Group entropy
0.820
0.489
-0.021
0.223**
0.010
-0.112
0.195**
-0.058
-0.027
0.040
0.142*
-0.031
12. Industry 1.905
0.677
0.110
0.016
-0.201**
0.068
-0.100
0.016
0.063
0.026
0.152*
-0.063
0.025
competitiveness
** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
* Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
N = 224.
198
D
.
Y
iu et al.
© Blackw
ell Pub
lishing Ltd 2005
Table II. Regression results on business group resources and group performance
Dependent variable: Return on assets
Predicted sign
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Control variables
Number of employees (ln)
-0.151* (0.002)
-0.201** (0.002)
-0.130* (0.002)
-0.176** (0.002)
-0.331***
Current ratio
0.294*** (0.003)
0.215** (0.003)
0.270*** (0.003)
0.207** (0.003)
-0.221**
Group diversification
0.006 (0.005)
0.000 (0.004)
0.013 (0.004)
0.001 (0.004)
-0.010
Industry competitiveness
0.151* (0.003)
0.152** (0.003)
0.124* (0.003)
0.135* (0.003)
0.106
†
Independent variables
Endowed resources via
Group history (age)
-
-0.134* (0.001)
-0.114* (0.001)
-0.134**
Government ownership
-
-0.270*** (0.009)
-0.247** (0.009)
-0.234***
Number of previous government
-
-0.141* (0.021)
-0.093
†
(0.019)
-0.125**
officials in top management
Groups transferred from
-
0.059 (0.006)
0.064 (0.006)
0.063
industrial bureau
Acquired resources via
Acquisition
+
0.137
†
(0.000)
0.105
†
(0.000)
0.086
†
Internal capability development
+
0.273*** (0.002)
0.241** (0.002)
0.224***
International diversification
+
0.099* (0.000)
0.126* (0.000)
1.497*
Correction for self-selection (
l)
-0.846**
R-square
0.12
0.21
0.22
0.28
c
2
(df ) = 82.82 (13)
Adjusted R-square
0.11
0.18
0.20
0.25
R-square change
0.12
0.09
0.10
0.16
Model F statistics
7.68***
7.04***
8.73***
7.61***
F statistics for change
7.68***
5.74***
7.09***
6.77***
N = 224. Standardized coefficients, and robust standard errors in parentheses, are reported. Robust standard errors were not presented with the two-step option.
†
p < 0.10, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Overall, all the models had strong model significance (p < 0.001 for the F-
statistics) and the R
2
s showed that the models explained a significant amount of
the dependent variable. Also, the change in R
2
of the hierarchical regression
models indicated that group’s developed resources had slightly greater incremen-
tal variance explained, compared to the endowed resources. This indicated the
increasing importance of self-developed market oriented resources in emerging
economies compared to the historical resources endowed from the pre-transition
period.
Results of the hypotheses tests include support for the fact that the age of a
business group is negatively related to its overall group performance (Hypothesis
1). In Model 2 of Table II, the coefficient of group age is negative and statistically
significant (p < 0.05). Hypothesis 2 predicts that there is a negative relationship
between government ownership and group performance. The findings show that
the coefficient is negative and statistically significant (p < 0.001). Hypothesis 2 is
strongly supported. Hypothesis 3 predicts that business groups with more CEO
and managers who previously worked in government have lower performance. As
shown in Model 2, the coefficient of CEO and managers with government expe-
rience is statistically significant at the 0.05 level, but it becomes weaker in the full
model (p < 0.10). As such, Hypothesis 3 is moderately supported. The last hypoth-
esis on endowed resources is that business groups that are transferred from gov-
ernment industrial bureaus perform worse than business groups that are not.
However, the coefficient is not statistically significant. Therefore, Hypothesis 4 is
not supported.
With regard to the set of hypotheses on group’s acquired/developed resources,
Hypothesis 5 predicts that business groups that pursue more acquisitions will
perform better. As shown in Model 3, acquisition intensity has a positive relation-
ship with group performance (p < 0.10). Therefore, Hypothesis 5 is marginally
supported. Hypothesis 6 predicts that internal capability development is positively
related to performance of a business group. There is strong support for this hypoth-
esis as the coefficient is positive and statistically significant (p < 0.001). Finally,
Hypothesis 7 predicts that there is a positive relationship between international
diversification and business group performance. The findings show that the coef-
ficient of international diversification is statistically significant at the p < 0.05 level.
Thus, Hypothesis 7 is supported.
Model 5 presents the results with the correction of the endogenous effects of
international diversification on performance. Following Heckman (1979), we
employed a two-stage estimation of the endogenous self-selection model, also
referred to as the treatment model (Greene, 1993). This approach for accounting
for endogeneity is adopted in previous studies such as Campa and Kedia (2002)
and Shaver (1998). We first recoded the international diversification into a binary
choice variable and regressed it by firm attributes including firm size and current
ratio, and industry competitiveness. Then, we ran the full model (Model 4) again
Business Group Performance
199
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
by replacing the international diversification variable with the probit estimates of
the probability to enter foreign countries obtained in the first step. As shown in
Model 5, the endogeneity problem is evidenced as the coefficient of
l, the self-
selection parameter, is negative and statistically significant at the 0.01 level. The
coefficient of international diversification, after correcting for the selection bias,
still has a positive and significant effect on group performance (p < 0.05).
DISCUSSION
In this study, we conceptualized business groups as the instrument, not only the
product, of institutional transition. Organizations are assigned the role of being
the agents of transformation. By taking this approach and building on the insti-
tutional and resource-based theories, the present study provides an opportunity to
examine the relationship between organizational resource portfolio and institu-
tional transition.
Endowed Resources
Business groups have a pool of mixed resources at a stage of institutional transi-
tion as old transitions fade away and new market institutions come into place. In
such settings, the endowed resources from the pre-transition period may become
a burden for business groups. The significance of the age variable in a negative
direction indicates that the more embedded the group is in the planned economy
the more likely that its performance will go down. It is easier and quicker for
younger groups to configure a new portfolio of resources that allows them greater
strategic flexibility to pursue different strategies for the new environment.
Frequently it is assumed that the key resource with which a business group needs
to be endowed is relations with key government authorities. The extensive writ-
ings on guanxi, or connections, in business in China are consistent with this per-
spective (cf. Tsang and Walls, 1998). Also, past literature stressed the importance
of the government as a resource provider to business groups. Granovetter (1994)
stated that the relations between governments and business groups are central in
shaping the business group’s ownership, authority structure, and relations of
groups to financial institutions. However, the evidence presented here calls these
beliefs into question.
Government ownership has great governance implications on group perfor-
mance. As the dominant owner of the group, government can control the use of
resources of a business group. For example, the association with the government
introduces forces into the strategic decision making of the firm that may not be
focused on profit maximization (Zhu, 1998). Also, the persistent dominance of gov-
ernment ownership in large firms such as business groups may indicate that the
200
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
accumulated unproductive resources in government-owned firms make them
difficult to attract alternative owners. This, again, highlights the urgency for
government-owned firms to reconfigure their resource portfolios as what is called
in this study. Diffused ownership may come after a competitive resource pool is
created in a firm.
Top management positions held by previous government officials can be a lia-
bility. A great challenge faced by former socialist managers and government offi-
cials is to understand and accept a new cognitive framework for doing business
and management (Child, 1993). Paradoxically, it is the uncertainty of the institu-
tional transition process itself that made managers incline to stick to the old rules
with which they are familiar. The environment has changed but the cognitive
mindsets of top management have not. Thus, it appears that ‘cognitive processes
must be put in place that are the reverse of those that led to institutionalization
in the first place’ (Johnson et al., 2000, p. 576).
However, the relationship between business groups that are transferred from
previous government industrial bureau and group performance was not statisti-
cally significant. The insignificance may be due to the strong normative pressure
of the previous institutional environment that gave rise to isomorphic organiza-
tional patterns under the hierarchical system (Child, 1993). As such, whether
groups are transferred from the government bureaus may not impose significant
heterogonous imprinting effects on firms. Alternatively, the insignificant relation-
ship may be because such a relationship is not a direct relationship but one medi-
ated by other factors such as restructuring efforts made after group formation. For
instance, the Shougang Group, one of the four core players in China’s steel indus-
try, was merged from 13 industrial ministries and became one of the largest
business groups in China. After the group formation, the Shougang Group
implemented a series of ‘catch-up’ actions, including divesting loss-making non-
core businesses, downsizing the core business slowly, raising capital in the stock
market, and generating resources for upgrading technology (Nolan and Yeung,
2001). Thus, restructuring efforts made by the group may be a mediating factor
on the relationship between group founding and performance. Future research
may explore this mediating relationship.
Acquired/Developed Resources
Prior research has tended to view business groups as uniform groups of entities.
The evidence here is that business groups can take significant steps to help their
performance after their initial formation. Those business groups that have proac-
tively sought to develop capabilities through acquisitions, internal development, or
international diversification result in better group performance. Among the three
means of resource acquisition, the findings showed that self-developed resources
have the strongest effect while the effect of acquisition is marginal.
Business Group Performance
201
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
The prominence of self-developed resources rather than acquired resources may
be due to the fact that the market for acquisition is still developing in an emergent
economy like China, and so the best potential acquisition firms do not come onto
the market. Second, back to the core argument of the resource-based view, capa-
bilities cannot be acquired. Compared to acquisition, longer-term horizon strate-
gies such as internal development and international diversification allow for a
greater depth and breadth of organizational learning and the generation of firm-
specific core competencies. The findings echo recent studies by Peng (2003) which
demonstrated that the pressures for firms to build competitive-based capabilities
are increasing when the economy is transitioning towards a more transactional
type economy.
Comparing the results of developed resources to those of endowed resources,
the present study supports the belief that the benefits given by networks are grad-
ually eclipsed by the growing importance of organizational capabilities as the
economy transits towards a market-based economy (Hoskisson et al., 2000; Peng,
2003). Besides, an implication drawn from the empirical findings of this study is
that a key constraint of institutional transition in emerging economies is that strate-
gic change may be hindered by the structural properties and the resource port-
folio of the firms. Thus, firms that adapt and build strategic capacity will perform
the best.
Future Research Agenda
Future research should seek to expand the understanding of how business groups
manage their resources to create value. One specific area of potential investiga-
tion about such management of interdependencies is the nature of the coordina-
tion between the business group and its affiliated firms. The two levels of the
organization likely have very different perceptions of resources and the necessary
management of those resources. Future researchers should explore the interaction
between those two levels of the organization.
An alternative area of potential investigation is how business groups restructure
themselves. For example, in China business groups found that success in the
domestic market was very easy. However, now there are large numbers of both
domestic and international competitors. The entry of China into the WTO will
only further intensify these competitive pressures. Thus, many business groups in
China today face the prospect of needing to restructure their businesses. The
ability to restructure those business groups that are performing poorly will become
a more critical issue in the future and merits investigation.
The evidence here is that relationships with government authorities are not a
positive, but a negative, impact on group performance. The most widely exam-
ined topic in China by researchers is the topic of guanxi, or connections among
parties. The evidence here calls into question the relevance of much of the prior
202
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
writings on guanxi without noting the changes in the institutional environment.
The development of greater transparency of accounting standards, advances in
the legal environment, and more consistent government regulation would be
expected to lead to lower needs for relationship based markets. Future research
should revisit how the importance of guanxi may be changing in this evolving
institutional environment.
The present findings are limited to a particular stage of the institutional tran-
sition process due to the cross-sectional nature of the data. Previously, Khanna
and Palepu (2000) found that the relationship between group diversification and
firm performance is curvilinear. In other words, the evolution of the institutional
context will alter the value-creating potential of business groups. Our results are
consistent with this finding. A longitudinal examination will allow a fuller picture
of business groups to be developed at different stages of the institutional transi-
tion process, and help to demonstrate that the institutional economics and
resource-based perspectives of business groups are complimentary with each other.
Also, the generalizability of our findings may be limited by the inclusion of busi-
ness groups in the sample only. Nonetheless, given that almost all major businesses
are part of a business group in the empirical context, China, it is debatable that
a comparable sample of independent firms could be located. Therefore, prospec-
tive research can analyse a broader sample consisting of independent firms and
business groups in other emerging economies.
Finally, the present findings provide insightful implications to policy makers in
emerging economies as business groups continue to be the focus of government’s
economic policies in these countries. It has been recognized in other settings that
the government in China does not have efficient control of its agents (Peng, 2000b).
Thus, effort by the government to encourage employment would not be expected
to produce the desired result. The political goal of maintaining employment is a
short-term benefit. The society will benefit more if, in the long run, business groups
become stronger and able to compete both domestically and internationally. Thus,
rather than focusing on political goals, it can be helpful for business groups to
develop resources and capabilities necessary to compete in a market economy.
NOTE
*The work described in this article was supported by research grants from the Earmarked Research
Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region (Project No. CUHK4092/98H).
REFERENCES
Ahlstrom, D. and Bruton, G. D. (2001). ‘Learning from successful local private firms in China: estab-
lishing legitimacy’. Academy of Management Executive, 15, 72–83.
Amsden, A. H. (1989). Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Business Group Performance
203
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Andrews, W. A. and Dowling, M. J. (1998). ‘Explaining performance changes in newly privatized
firms’. Journal of Management Studies, 35, 601–17.
Aoki, M. (1982). ‘Business groups in a market economy’. European Economic Review, 19, 53–70.
Barney, J. (1991). ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage’. Journal of Management, 17,
99–120.
Boycko, M., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1995). A Theory of Privatization. Mimeo. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University.
Campa, J. M. and Kedia, S. (2002). ‘Explaining the diversification discount’. Journal of Finance, 57,
1731–62.
Caves, R. and Uekusa, M. (1976). Industrial Organization in Japan. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution.
Chang, S. J. (1996). ‘An evolutionary perspective on diversification and corporate restructuring: entry,
exit, and economic performance during 1981–89’. Strategic Management Journal, 17, 587–611.
Chang, S. J. (2003). ‘Ownership structure, expropriation, and performance of group-affiliated com-
panies in Korea’. Academy of Management Journal, 46, 238–53.
Chang, S. J. and Choi, U. (1988). ‘Strategy, structure, and performance of Korean business groups:
a transactions cost approach’. Journal of Industrial Economics, 37, 141–59.
Chang, S. J. and Hong, J. (2000). ‘Economic performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea:
intragroup resource sharing and internal business transactions’. Academy of Management Journal,
43, 429–48.
Chatterjee, S. and Singh, H. (1999). ‘Are tradeoffs inherent in diversification moves? A simultane-
ous model for type of diversification and mode of expansion decisions’. Management Science, 45,
25–41.
Child, J. (1993). ‘Society and enterprise between hierarchy and market’. In Child, J., Crozier, M.
and Mayntz, R. (Eds), Societal Change Between Market and Organization. Aldershot: Averbury,
203–26.
China Economic Yearbook (2000). Beijing: China Economic Yearbook Press.
China Industrial Development Report (1999). Beijing: Economics and Management Publishing.
China Statistical Yearbook (2000). Beijing: China Statistical Press.
Cook, K. S. (1977). ‘Exchange and power in networks of interorganizational relationships’. Sociologi-
cal Quarterly, 18, 62–82.
Finkelstein, S. and Hambrick, D. C. (1990). ‘Top management team tenure and organizational out-
comes: the moderating effect of managerial discretion’. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35,
484–503.
Granovetter, M. (1994). ‘Business groups’. In Smelser, N. J. and Swedberg, R. (Eds), The Handbook of
Economic Sociology. New York: Russell Sage, 453–75.
Greene, W. H. (1993). Econometric Analysis, 2nd edition. New York: Macmillan.
Guillén, M. F. (1997). ‘Business groups in economic development’. Academy of Management Best Paper
Proceedings, Academy of Management Annual Meeting at Boston, USA, 170–4.
Guillén, M. F. (2000). ‘Business groups in emerging economies: a resource-based view’. Academy of
Management Journal, 43, 362–80.
Hambrick, D. C. and Mason, P. (1984). ‘Upper echelons: the organization as a reflection of its top
managers’. Academy of Management Review, 9, 193–206.
Hannan, M. T. and Freeman, J. (1984). ‘Structural inertia and organizational change’. American
Sociological Review, 49, 149–64.
Heckman, J. (1979). ‘Sample selection bias as a specification error’. Econometrica, 47, 133–9.
Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., Johnson, R. A. and Moesel, D. (1996). ‘The market for corporate
control and firm innovation’. Academy of Management Journal, 39, 1084–109.
Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E. and Kim, H. (1997). ‘International diversification: effects on innovations
and firm performance on product-diversified firms’. Academy of Management Journal, 40, 767–98.
Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M. and Wright, M. (2000). ‘Strategy in emerging economies’.
Academy of Management Journal, 43, 249–67.
Johnson, G., Smith, S. and Codling, B. (2000). ‘Microprocesses of institutional change in the context
of privatization’. Academy of Management Review, 25, 572–80.
Keister, L. A. (1998). ‘Engineering growth: business group structure and firm performance in China’s
transition economy’. American Journal of Sociology, 104, 404–40.
Keister, L. A. (2000). Chinese Business Groups: The Structure and Impact of Interfirm Relations During Eco-
nomic Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
204
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (1997). ‘Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging markets’.
Harvard Business Review, 75, 41–51.
Khanna T. and Palepu, K. (2000). ‘The future of business groups in emerging markets: long-run
evidence from Chile’. Academy of Management Journal, 43, 268–85.
Khanna, T. and Rivkin, J. W. (2000). Ties That Bind Business Groups: Evidence from an Emerging Economy.
Mimeo. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Khanna, T. and Yafeh, Y. (1999). Business Groups and Risk Sharing Around the World. Mimeo. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University.
Kim, H., Hoskisson, R. E., Tihanyi, L. and Hong, J. (2004). ‘The evolution and restructuring of
diversified business groups in emerging markets: the lessons from chaebols in Korea’. Asia Pacific
Journal of Management, 21, 25–48.
Kobrin, S. J. (1991). ‘An empirical analysis of the determinants of global integration’. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 12, Special issue, 17–37.
Kock, C. J. and Guillén, M. (2001). ‘Strategy and structure in developing countries: business groups
as an evolutionary response to opportunities for unrelated diversification’. Industrial and Corpo-
rate Change, 10, 77–113.
Kornai, J. (1980). Economics of Shortage. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Leff, N. (1978). ‘Industrial organization and entrepreneurship in the developing countries: the eco-
nomic groups’. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 26, 661–75.
Makino, S., Lau, C. M. and Yeh, R. S. (2002). ‘Asset-exploitation versus asset-seeking: implications
for location choice of foreign direct investment from newly industrialized economies’. Journal of
International Business Studies, 33, 403–21.
Nakatani, I. (1984). ‘The role of financial corporate grouping’. In Aoki, M. (Ed.), Economic Analysis
of the Japanese Firm. New York: North-Holland.
Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G. (1982). En Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University.
Nolan, P. (2001). China and the Global Business Revolution. New York: Palgrave.
Nolan, P. and Yeung, G. (2001). ‘Large firms and catch up in a transition economy: the case of
Shougang Group in China’. Economics of Planning, 34, 159–78.
Ocasio, W. (1997). ‘Towards an attention-based view of the firm’. Strategic Management Journal,
Summer Special Issue, 18, 187–206.
Palepu, K. (1985). ‘Diversification strategy, profit performance, and the entropy measure’. Strategic
Management Journal, 6, 239–55.
Peng, M. W. (2000a). Business Strategies in Transition Economies. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Peng, M. W. (2000b). ‘Controlling the foreign agent: how governments deal with multinationals in
a transition economy’. Management International Review, 40, 141–66.
Peng, M. W. (2001). ‘How entrepreneurs create wealth in transition economies’. Academy of Manage-
ment Executive, 15, 95–110.
Peng, M. W. (2003). ‘Institutional transition and strategic choices’. Academy of Management Review, 28,
275–96.
Penrose, E. T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: Wiley.
Perotti, E. C. and Gelfer, S. (2001). ‘Red barons or robber barons? Governance and investment in
Russian financial-industrial groups’. European Economic Review, 45, 1601–17.
Podsakoff, P. M. and Organ, D. W. (1986). ‘Self-reports in organizational research: problems and
prospects’. Journal of Management, 12, 531–44.
Roth, K. and Kostova, T. (2003). ‘Organizational coping with institutional upheaval in transition
economies’. Journal of World Business, 38, 314–30.
Schoenecker, T. S. and Cooper, A. C. (1998). ‘The role of firm resources and organizational attributes
in determining entry timing: a cross-industry study’. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 1127–2243.
Schwartz, A. (1992). A Nation in Waiting: Indonesia in the 1990s. Sydney: Allen & Unwin.
Shaver, J. M. (1998). ‘Accounting for endogeneity when assessing strategy performance: does entry
mode choice affect FDI survival?’. Management Science, 44, 571–85.
Stark, D. (1996). ‘Recombinant property in East European capitalism’. American Journal of Sociology,
101, 993–1027.
Strachan, H. W. (1976). Family and Other Business Groups in Economic Development: The Case of Nicaragua.
New York: Praeger.
Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). ‘Social structure and organizations’. In March, J. G. (Ed.), Handbook of
Organizations. Chicago, IL: Rand McNally, 142–93.
Business Group Performance
205
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005
Tallman, S. and Li, J. (1996). ‘Effects of international diversity and product diversity on the perfor-
mance of multinational firms’. Academy of Management Journal, 39, 179–96.
Tsang E. and Walls W. K. (1998). ‘Can guanxi be a source of competitive advantage for doing busi-
ness in China’. Academy of Management Executive, 12, 64–73.
Uhlenbruck, K., Meyer, K. and Hitt, M. A. (2003). ‘Organizational transformation in transition
economies: resource-based and organizational learning perspectives’. Journal of Management
Studies, 40, 257–82.
White, L. J. (1974). Industrial Concentration and Economic Power in Pakistan. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
versity Press.
Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E. and Peng, M. W. (2005). ‘Guest editor’s introduction:
Strategy research in emerging economies: Challenging the conventional wisdom’. Journal of
Management Studies, 42, 1, 1–33.
Zahra, S. A., Ireland, D. R., Gutierrez, I. and Hitt, M. A. (2000). ‘Privatization and entrepreneur-
ial transformation: emerging issues and a future research agenda’. Academy of Management Review,
25, 509–24.
Zajac, E., Kraatz, M. and Bresser, R. (2000). ‘Modeling the dynamics of strategic fit’. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 21, 429–54.
Zhu, T. (1998). ‘Theory of contract and ownership choice in public enterprises under reformed
socialism: the case of China’s TVEs’. China Economic Review, 9, 59–72.
206
D. Yiu et al.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2005