Asheim, Coenen (2005) Knowledge bases and regional innovation systems comparing Nordic clusters

background image

Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

Knowledge bases and regional innovation systems:

Comparing Nordic clusters

Bjørn T. Asheim

a

,

b

,

c

,

, Lars Coenen

a

,

b

a

Department of Social and Economic Geography, Lund University, Sweden

b

Centre for Innovation, Research and Competence in the Learning Economy (CIRCLE), Lund University, Sweden

c

Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture (TIK), University of Oslo, Norway

Received 3 October 2004; received in revised form 26 January 2005; accepted 7 March 2005

Available online 27 June 2005

Abstract

The analysis of the importance of different types of regional innovation systems must take place within a context of the actual

knowledge base of various industries in the economy, as the innovation processes of firms are strongly shaped by their specific
knowledge base. In this paper, we shall distinguish between two types of knowledge base: analytical and synthetic. These types
indicate different mixes of tacit and codified knowledge, codification possibilities and limits, qualifications and skills, required
organisations and institutions involved, as well as specific competitive challenges from a globalising economy, which have
different implications for different sectors of industry, and, thus, for the kind of innovation support needed. The traditional
constellation of industrial clusters surrounded by innovation supporting organisations, constituting a regional innovation system,
is nearly always to be found in contexts of industries with a synthetic knowledge base (e.g. engineering-based industries), while
the existence of regional innovation systems as an integral part of a cluster will normally be the case of industries-based on an
analytical knowledge base (e.g. science-based industries, such as IT and bio-tech). In the discussion of different types of regional
innovation systems five empirical illustrations from a Nordic comparative project on SMEs and regional innovation systems
will be used: the furniture industry in Salling, Denmark; the wireless communication industry in North Jutland, Denmark;
the functional food industry in Scania, Sweden; the food industry in Rogaland, Norway and the electronics industry in Horten,
Norway. We argue that in terms of innovation policy the regional level often provides a grounded approach embedded in networks
of actors acknowledging the importance of the knowledge base of an industry.
© 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Regional innovation systems; Knowledge bases; Nordic countries

Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: Bjorn.Asheim@keg.lu.se (B.T. Asheim),

Lars.Coenen@keg.lu.se (L. Coenen).

1. Introduction

Over the past two decades social scientist and pol-

icy makers have been paying more and more atten-
tion to regions as designated sites of innovation and

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

doi:10.1016/j.respol.2005.03.013

background image

1174

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

competitiveness in the globalising economy. The pop-
ularity of this argument can be traced back to various
empirical studies of regional success stories, such as the
rapid economic growth of networked SMEs in indus-
trial districts in the ‘Third Italy’ (

Asheim, 2000

), the

exemplar industrial system of Silicon Valley (

Saxenian,

1994

) as well as other examples of successful regional

clustering in most developed as well as developing
economies (

Porter, 1990

). These studies all draw on the

common rationale that territorial agglomeration pro-
vides the best context for an innovation-based global-
ising economy because of localised learning processes
and ‘sticky’ knowledge grounded in social interaction
(

Asheim, 2002; Asheim and Isaksen, 2002; Gertler,

2004

). They have emphasised the significance of the

regional level in economic development in addition
to—and sometimes over—the national level.

Two concepts belonging to the territorial innovation

theory family (

Moulaert and Sekia, 2003

) have demon-

strated particular resonance in academic and policy
circles: regional innovation systems (RIS) and clusters
(

Cooke et al., 2004; Porter, 2000

). Even though both

concepts are closely related, they should not be con-
flated.

Isaksen and Hauge (2002, p. 14)

define the latter

as “a concentration of ‘inter-dependent’ firms within
the same or adjacent industrial sectors in a small geo-
graphic area”. A RIS, on the other hand, is defined
as “interacting knowledge generation and exploitation
subsystems linked to global, national and other regional
systems” (

Cooke, 2004

, p. 3). In principle it stretches

across several sectors in the regional economy, given
that firms and knowledge organisations interact sys-
tematically (i.e. consistently). From this follows that
clusters and RIS can (and often do) co-exist in the same
territory. In a policy context it is nonetheless crucial to
acknowledge the sector specificity of clusters and the
more generic sector orientation of RIS.

This paper takes up the issue of regionalising inno-

vation policy by looking from a bottom-up perspective
at the linkage between regional innovation systems
and clusters. Arguing strongly against any universally
valid, ‘one-size-fits-all’ model, we contend that in line
with its sector specificity a differentiation needs to be
made on the basis of the cluster’s knowledge base. For
clusters with a synthetic (engineering-based) knowl-
edge base, the logic behind the regional innovation
system (as well as regional innovation policy) is to
support and strengthen localised learning of an exist-

ing industrial specialisation, i.e. to promote historical
technological trajectories-based on sticky knowledge.
We call this the ex-post approach. In the case of an ana-
lytical (science-based) knowledge-based cluster, it is a
question of promoting new economic activity, requiring
close and systemic industry–university co-operation
and interaction in the context of, e.g. science parks and
incubator centres. We call this the ex-ante approach.
Based on this distinction we compare five Nordic
clusters across a range of differing industries and
draw conclusions for the regionalisation of innovation
policy.

Section

2

introduces the notion of the learning econ-

omy as well as the main differentiation track: industrial
knowledge bases. Section

3

introduces the concept

of regional innovation system. Section

4

presents an

overview of the varieties of regional innovation sys-
tems, while Section

5

provides the empirical illustra-

tions from a Nordic comparative project on SMEs and
regional innovation systems. Finally, conclusions and
policy implications are given in Section

6

.

2. Providing context: the learning economy and
industrial knowledge bases

Both the knowledge-based as well as learning econ-

omy rationale argue that in the globalising economy
knowledge is the most strategic resource and learn-
ing the most fundamental activity for competitiveness
(

Lundvall, 1992; OECD, 1996

). However, in academic

as well as policy oriented discourses these two concepts
have from time to time taken on different meanings with
potential importance for the theoretical understanding
of the contemporary economy as well as for policy
implications. Lundvall has always preferred to talk
about the contemporary global economy as a ‘learn-
ing economy’, while the OECD (at least the economic
sections), being influenced by the US, has instead more
often used ‘the knowledge-based’ economy. This dif-
ference can basically be traced back to the taxonomic
differentiation between high-, medium- and low-tech
industries as suggested and endorsed by the

OECD

(1986)

. Though the initial discussion was carefully

launched, offering many necessary qualifications, it
seems that the high-tech fascination has taken on a life
of its own, limiting knowledge-intensive and innovative
activities exclusively to high-tech industries, such as

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1175

ICT equipment or pharmaceuticals. Under this assump-
tion R&D intensity is often equated with innovation
across-the-board (

Hirsch-Kreinsen et al., 2003

).

The key question in this context remains how inno-

vation should be understood and treated, as both defi-
nitions basically refer to the importance of innovation
as a source of competitive advantage in a globalis-
ing economy. We follow

Edquist (1997)

in his broad

definition of innovation as new creations of economic
significance. This encompasses radically new creations
as well as new combinations of existing elements,
includes novelty of either a material or an intangi-
ble kind and refers to what is produced as well as
how goods and services are produced. Moreover, we
prefer to argue in terms of the learning economy
rather than the knowledge-based economy because of
its more inclusive and dynamic notion of innovation.
In a learning economy innovation is understood as
an interactive learning process, which is socially and
territorially embedded and culturally and institution-
ally contextualized (

Lundvall, 1992

). It emphasizes a

dynamic approach to innovation rather than the more
static approach adopted in the knowledge-based econ-
omy that emphasizes access to a stock of specialised
knowledge (

Lundvall and Archibugi, 2001

). In addi-

tion, this conceptualisation means an extension of the
range of branches, firm-sizes and regions that can
be viewed as innovative, also to include traditional,
non R&D intensive branches (e.g. the importance of
design in making furniture manufactures competitive
and moving them up the value-added chain). Further-
more, knowledge flows within a distributed knowledge
base (

Smith, 2000

)—which more and more substitutes

intra-firm (or intramural) knowledge bases (which con-
stitutes the basis for the OECD taxonomy of R&D
intensity)—taking place between industries with very
different degrees of R&D intensity, further weaken the
distinction between high-tech and low-tech industries.
(e.g. when food and beverage firms produce functional
food based on inputs from bio-tech firms).

Nonetheless, this position calls for a certain degree

of modification. The learning economy approach was
developed in a national context of small-sized indus-
tries relying on incremental, non R&D based product
innovations (e.g. Denmark). A problematic aspect of
learning organisations as well as the learning economy
in general has been its focus on ‘catching up’ learning
(i.e. learning by doing and using) based on incremental

innovations, and not on radical innovations requiring
the creation of new knowledge. It is, of course, impor-
tant to underline ‘the tremendous importance of incre-
mental innovation, learning by doing, by using and by
interacting in the process of technical change and dif-
fusion of innovations’ (

Freeman, 1993

, pp. 9–10). This

is typically what co-ordinated market economies, such
as Denmark and the other Nordic countries are very
efficient at through knowledge diffusing (and learn-
ing) organisations, with a strong developed absorptive
capacity, but being weaker when it comes to knowl-
edge creation as input for radical innovations (

Hall and

Soskice, 2001

). In a long-term perspective, however,

it will be increasingly difficult for the reproduction
and growth of a learning economy to primarily rely
on incremental improvements of products and pro-
cesses, for example, in the form of imitation, and not on
basically new products (i.e. radical innovations). This
would be even more problematic if it is based on exoge-
nous learning. According to Nonaka and Reinm¨oller,
‘no matter how great the efficiency and speed of exoge-
nous learning, it will not substitute for the endoge-
nous creation of knowledge. The faster knowledge is
absorbed, the greater the dependence on the sources of
knowledge becomes’ (

Nonaka and Reinm¨oller, 1998

,

pp. 425–426). In a dynamic and rapidly changing con-
temporary globalising economy it is, thus, necessary to
pay attention to knowledge creation as a process that
is of equal importance to the processes of learning and
competence building.

This modification acknowledges

Cooke (in press)

critique of the learning economy. He argues that the
semantic emphasis on ‘learning’ has become increas-
ingly myoptic with regard to the actual content of
the learning processes at hand. We, therefore, argue
that it is important to keep in mind that both learning
and knowledge remain means to achieve competitive-
ness (through innovation) rather than intrinsic goals
per se. Through processes of globalisation, i.e. increas-
ing inter-connectedness between different parts of the
world, competition has become more and more intense.
In a globalising economy competitive advantage is
based on exploitation of unique competencies and
resources (which thus excludes outdated and second-
hand knowledge). A firm or a region competes on the
basis of what they have which is unique in relation to
their competitors. A strategic perspective in the con-
temporary global economy is, thus, how to develop

background image

1176

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

such unique competencies and resources in order to
foster competitiveness (

Porter, 1990

).

Maskell et al. (1998)

argue that the only economic

production factors not subjected to ubiquitification, i.e.
the process of conventional production factors (e.g.
labor, capital, equipment, raw materials) becoming
more available across the world for the same price, are
localised, “sticky” knowledge including collective tacit
as well as disembodied codified knowledge (

Asheim,

1999

). Generally, territorial agglomerations play an

important role when it comes to the regional embedding
of knowledge and learning processes. In the same way,
as knowledge is nationally embedded due to sectoral
specialisations as well as political and cultural organ-
isations and institutions, knowledge is also regionally
embedded as a result of a historically produced territo-
rial division of labour. The exploitation of localisation
economies in territorial agglomerations accounts for an
important factor when regional specialisation should be
explained. There are numerous examples of once suc-
cessful agglomerations that were profitable and com-
petitive throughout history. However, these once suc-
cessful regional clusters can also run into serious prob-
lems as a result of path dependency resulting in negative
‘lock-in’ tendencies, i.e. that the dominating techno-
logical trajectory is not modified or changed before
the industry is out competed, due to lack of innovation.
Many industrial districts in the third Italy could be used
as illustrating cases. Most of them have only relied on
incremental innovations-based on tacit or in a minor-
ity of cases also synthetic knowledge, which normally
do not have the capacity of changing technological tra-
jectories. Against this background, regional policy has
clearly moved away from a re-active notion of redis-
tributing welfare to a pro-active position at the heart
of economic development. The development of the
endogenous capacity of regions to innovate in order to
create competitive advantage is today often referred to
as ‘regional constructed advantage’ in which the estab-
lishment and formation of regional innovation systems
plays a strategic role (

Cooke and Leydesdorff, in press

).

There is no single optimal strategy in this respect.

We argue that the innovation process of firms and
industries is particularly dependent on their specific
knowledge base (

Asheim and Gertler, 2005

). Here we

will distinguish between two types of knowledge base:
‘analytical’ and ‘synthetic’ (

Laestadius, 1998

), which

are summarized in

Table 1

. In its philosophical mean-

ing, analytical refers to the way of reasoning by which
the truth of a proposition is established independent
of fact or experience involving inference from gen-
eral principle. Synthetic, on the other hand, pertains to
knowledge having a truth value determined by obser-
vation or facts.

Here, an analytical knowledge base refers to indus-

trial settings, where scientific knowledge is highly
important, and where knowledge creation is often based
on cognitive and rational processes, or on formal mod-
els. Examples are genetics, biotechnology and gen-
eral information technology. Both basic and applied
research as well as systematic development of prod-
ucts and processes, are relevant activities. Compa-
nies typically have their own R&D departments but
they rely also on the research results of universities
and other research organisations in their innovation
process. University–industry links and respective net-
works, thus, are important and more frequent than in the
other type of knowledge base. Knowledge inputs and
outputs are in this type of knowledge base more often
codified than in the other type. This does not imply that
tacit knowledge is irrelevant, since there are always
both kinds of knowledge involved and needed in the
process of knowledge creation and innovation (

Nonaka

et al., 2000; Johnson and Lundvall, 2001

). The fact that

codification is more frequent is due to several reasons:
knowledge inputs are often based on reviews of existing
studies, knowledge generation is based on the applica-
tion of scientific principles and methods, knowledge
processes are more formally organised (e.g. in R&D
departments) and outcomes tend to be documented in
reports, electronic files or patent descriptions. Knowl-
edge application is in the form of new products or
processes, and there are more radical innovations than
in the other knowledge type. An important route of
knowledge application is new firms and spin-off com-
panies which are occasionally formed on the basis of
radically new inventions or products.

A synthetic knowledge base refers to industrial set-

tings, where the innovation takes place mainly through
the application of existing knowledge or through
new combinations of knowledge. Often this occurs in
response to the need to solve specific problems coming
up in the interaction with clients and suppliers. Indus-
try examples include plant engineering, specialised
advanced industrial machinery, and shipbuilding. Prod-
ucts are often ‘one-off’ or produced in small series.

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1177

Table 1
Synthetic vs. analytic knowledge base

Synthetic

Analytic

Innovation by application or novel combination of existing

knowledge

Innovation by creation of new knowledge

Importance of applied, problem related knowledge (engineering)

often through inductive processes

Importance of scientific knowledge often based on deductive
processes and formal models

Interactive learning with clients and suppliers

Research collaboration between firms (R&D department) and
research organisations

Dominance of tacit knowledge due to more concrete know-how,

craft and practical skill

Dominance of codified knowledge due to documentation in
patents and publications

Mainly incremental innovation

More radical innovation

Source:

Asheim and Gertler (2005)

.

R&D is in general less important than in the first type.
If so, it takes the form of applied research, but more
often it is in the form of product or process develop-
ment. University–industry links are relevant, but they
are clearly more in the field of applied research and
development than in basic research. Knowledge is cre-
ated less in a deductive process or through abstraction,
but more often in an inductive process of testing, experi-
mentation, computer-based simulation or through prac-
tical work. Knowledge embodied in the respective tech-
nical solution or engineering work is at least partially
codified. However, tacit knowledge seems to be more
important than in the first type, in particular due to
the fact that knowledge often results from experience
gained at the workplace, and through learning by doing,
using and interacting. Compared to the first knowl-
edge type, there is more concrete know-how, craft and
practical skill required in the knowledge production
and circulation process. These are often provided by
professional and polytechnic schools, or by on-the-
job training. The innovation process is often oriented
towards the efficiency and reliability of new solutions,
or the practical utility and user friendliness of prod-
ucts from the perspective of the customers. Overall,
this leads to a rather incremental way of innovation,
dominated by the modification of existing products and
processes. Since these types of innovation are less dis-
ruptive to existing routines and organisations, most of
them take place in existing firms, whereas spin-offs are
relatively less frequent

1

Table 1

.

1

Pavitt (1984, pp. 353–65)

offers a three-way taxonomy of indus-

tries based on the predominant nature and sources of technical
change. Supplier-dominated industries include agriculture and tra-

3. Regional innovation systems and localised
learning

The regional innovation system can be thought of

as the institutional infrastructure supporting innovation
within the production structure of a region. Thus, in
case the following two subsystems of actors are system-
atically engaged in interactive learning (

Cooke et al.,

1998

) it can be argued that a regional innovation sys-

tem is in place. (1) The regional production structure
or knowledge exploitation subsystem which consists
mainly of firms, often displaying clustering tendencies.
(2) The regional supportive infrastructure or knowl-
edge generation subsystem which consists of public
and private research laboratories, universities and col-
leges, technology transfer agencies, vocational training
organisations, etc. Furthermore,

Cooke et al. (1998)

emphasise the mainly informal institutional context
(i.e. norms, trust and routines) in which such interac-
tive learning takes place. This dynamic and complex
interaction constitutes what is commonly labelled sys-
tems of innovation (

Edquist, 1997

), i.e. systems under-

stood as interaction networks (

Kaufmann and T¨odtling,

2001

).

ditional manufacturing sectors such as textiles. Production-intensive
industries can be further subdivided into scale-intensive sectors such
as steel, consumer durables and automobiles, and specialized sup-
plier sectors such as machinery and instruments. Science-based
industries include electronics and chemicals (including pharma-
ceuticals). Our observations about industries with synthetic knowl-
edge bases correspond closely to those sectors encompassed by the
first two of Pavitt’s categories (supplier-dominated and production-
intensive). Similarly, the analytical category corresponds directly to
Pavitt’s science-based industries.

background image

1178

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

Taking each element of the term in turn (

Asheim

and Cooke, 1999

), the concept of region highlights an

important level of governance of economic processes
between the national level and the level above the local
or municipal level (

Cooke and Leydesdorff, in press

).

Regions are important bases of economic co-ordination
at the meso-level, although the level of regional admin-
istration can differ quite a lot across various countries.
In varying degrees, regional governance is expressed
in both private representative organisations, such as
branches of industry associations and chambers of
commerce, and public organisations, such as regional
agencies with powers devolved from the national (or,
within the European Union, supra-national) level to
promote enterprise and innovation support (

Asheim

et al., 2003a; Cooke et al., 2000

).

The systemic dimension of the RIS derives in part

from the associational character of innovation net-
works (

Cooke and Morgan, 1998

). Such relationships,

to be systemic, must involve some degree of inter-
dependence, though to varying degrees. Likewise, not
all such systemic relations need to be regionally con-
tained, but many are.

2

As the interactive mode of inno-

vation grows in importance, these relations are more
likely to become regionally contained, for example,
in the case of specialised suppliers with a specific
technology or knowledge base. Such suppliers often
depend on tacit knowledge, face-to-face interaction
and trust-based relations and, thus, benefit from co-
operation with customers in regional clusters, while
capacity subcontractors are increasingly sourced glob-
ally. Further reinforcing the systemic character of the
RIS is the prevalence of a set of attitudes, values, norms,
routines and expectations—described by some as a
distinctive ‘regional culture’—that influences the prac-
tices of firms in the region. It is this common regional
culture—itself the product of commonly experienced
institutional forces—that shapes the way that firms
interact with one another in the regional economy.

Thus, we strongly disagree with

Bathelt (2003)

, who

argues that “it seems questionable that region-specific
innovation and production processes are typically asso-
ciated with the existence of regional innovation sys-
tems. To assume that such small-scale systems exist

2

In a recent study,

Carlsson (2004)

shows that the majority of

theoretical as well as empirical analyses of innovation systems have
a regional focus.

bears the risk of underestimating the importance of
those institutions which are negotiated and defined at
the level of the nation state. In reality, however, regional
and national innovation contexts are fundamentally dif-
ferent. Regional production configurations are often
dependent on structures and developments which are
shaped and take place outside the region” (

Bathelt,

2003

, p. 797).

3

The key to the disagreement lies in the application

by Bathelt of social systems theory, which replaces
the element/relation dichotomy of the innovation sys-
tems approach with a system/environment dichotomy
(

Kaufmann and T¨odtling, 2001

). This leads Bathelt to

believe that one of the core problems of the regional
innovation system is “that it portrays the region as
an entity which hosts a large part of an economic
value chain and has a governance structure of its own,
independent from its environment” (

Bathelt, 2003

, p.

796). Aside from the formal systems theoretical argu-
ments, there is no substantial theory to corroborate this
statement. Empirically it may be shown that regions
can in fact contain large parts of a value chain (e.g.
Italian industrial districts) as well as having a rela-
tive autonomous government structure (e.g. regions in
federal countries, such as Baden–W¨urttemberg in Ger-
many and Catalonia and the Basque country in Spain).
Furthermore, in a globalising economy characterised
by vertical disintegration and distributed knowledge
bases, the important perspective ought to be the inter-
dependences
between regions and nations, where the
deciding criteria must be the location of core activi-
ties (and not the whole value chain as such) and the
relative importance of their connections to regional
knowledge infrastructures. With the possible exception
of the US, the argument that “production configura-
tions are often dependent on structures and develop-
ments which are shaped and take place outside” of
the actual territory could as easily apply to most small
and medium-sized countries as to regions, especially
if being members of supra-national organisations such

3

In a more recent article

Bathelt (2005)

once more underlines his

position by arguing that ‘at this geographical level (i.e. a region, my
addition), it is unlikely that a self-referential system can develop
because regions are strongly dependent on national institutions
and other external influences and lack important political decision-
making competencies

. . .. Regional production configurations hardly

have the potential to gain and retain structural independence and
reproduce their basic structure’.

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1179

as the EU, ‘in which’ region formation ‘has and con-
tinues to be evolved apace’ (

Cooke, in press

).

Cooke

(in press)

refers to Bathelt’s position as Listian ‘writ-

ing that only nations (presumably meaning states since
there are many nations without full economic gover-
nance powers) have specificity and that they may also
be closed systems’.

Yet it is essential to recognise the, by inference,

inter-locked character of a region in a wider geograph-
ical context (

Howells, 1999

). But even if research has

revealed that the regional level is neither always nor
even normally sufficient for firms to stay innovative
and competitive (

Isaksen, 1999

), and that the learn-

ing process becomes increasingly inserted into var-
ious forms of networks and innovation systems (at
regional, national and inter-national levels), the con-
tinuous importance of the regional level is confirmed
by results from a European comparative cluster sur-
vey (

Isaksen, 2005

). This study shows that regional

resources and collaboration are of major importance
in stimulating economic activity in the clusters. How-
ever, the survey found an increased presence of MNCs
in many clusters, and also that firms in the clus-
ters increasingly source major components and per-
form assembly manufacturing outside of the clusters
(

Isaksen, 2005

). Also

T¨odtling and Trippl (2005)

found

empirical support for clustering because of the impor-
tance of social interaction, trust and local institutions.
Yet they also note that both local and distant networks
are often needed for successful co-operative projects,
in particular for projects of innovation and product
development when it is usually necessary to combine
both local and non-local skills and competences in
order to go beyond the limits of the region (see also

Asheim and Herstad, 2003; Bathelt et al., 2004; Cooke
et al., 2000

).

4. Varieties of regional innovation systems

The ‘innovation system’ concept can be understood

in both a narrow as well as a broad sense. A narrow def-
inition of the innovation system primarily incorporates
the R&D functions of universities, public and private
research institutes and corporations, reflecting a top-
down model of innovation as exemplified by the triple
helix approach (

Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff, 2000

). A

broader conception of the innovation systems includes

‘all parts and aspects of the economic structure and the
institutional set-up affecting learning as well as search-
ing and exploring’ (

Lundvall, 1992

, p. 12). This broad

definition incorporates the elements of a bottom-up,
interactive innovation model which alternatively could
be called ‘learning regions’ (

Asheim, 2001

).

In order to reflect the conceptual variety and empir-

ical richness of the relationships linking the produc-
tion structure to the ‘institutional set-up’ in a region,

Asheim (1998)

distinguishes between three types of

RISs (see also

Cooke, 1998; Asheim and Isaksen,

2002

). The first type may be denoted as territorially

embedded regional innovation systems, where firms
(primarily those employing synthetic knowledge) base
their innovation activity mainly on localised, inter-
firm learning processes stimulated by the conjunc-
tion of geographical and relational proximity with-
out much direct interaction with knowledge generat-
ing organisations (i.e. R&D institutes and universi-
ties). This type is similar to what

Cooke (1998)

calls

‘grassroots RIS’, and implies the broader definition
of innovation systems described by

Lundvall (1992)

above.

The best examples of territorially embedded

regional innovation systems are networks of SMEs in
industrial districts. Thus, in Italy’s Emilia-Romagna,
for example, the innovation system can be described
as territorially embedded within that particular region
(

Granovetter, 1985

). These territorially embedded

systems provide bottom-up, network-based support
through, for example, technology centres, innovation
networks, or centres for real service providing mar-
ket research and intelligence services, to promote
the ‘adaptive technological and organisational learn-
ing in territorial context’ (

Storper and Scott, 1995

,

p. 513).

Another type of RIS is the regionally networked

innovation system. The firms and organisations are
also embedded in a specific region and characterised
by localised, interactive learning. However, through
the intentional strengthening of the region’s institu-
tional infrastructure, for example, through a stronger,
more developed role for regionally based R&D insti-
tutes, vocational training organisations and other local
organisations involved in firms’ innovation processes
these systems have a more planned character involv-
ing public–private co-operation. The networked sys-
tem is commonly regarded as the ideal-type of RIS: a

background image

1180

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

regional cluster of firms surrounded by a regional ‘sup-
porting’ institutional infrastructure.

Cooke (1998)

also

calls this type ‘network RIS’. The network approach
is most typical of Germany, Austria and the Nordic
countries.

The regionally networked innovation system is a

result of policy intervention to increase innovation
capacity and collaboration. SMEs, for example, may
have to supplement their informal knowledge (charac-
terised by a high tacit component) with competence
arising from more systematic research and develop-
ment in order to carry out more radical innovations.
In the long run, most firms cannot rely exclusively on
informal localised learning, but must also gain access to
wider pools of both analytical and synthetic knowledge
on a national and global basis. The creation of region-
ally networked innovation systems through increased
co-operation with local universities and R&D insti-
tutes, or through the establishment of technology trans-
fer agencies, may provide access to knowledge and
competence that supplements firms’ locally derived
competence. This not only increases their collective
innovative capacity, but may also serve to counteract
technological ‘lock-in’ (the inability to deviate from
an established but outmoded technological trajectory)
within regional clusters of firms.

The third main type of RIS, the regionalised

national innovation system, differs from the two pre-
ceding types in several ways. First, parts of industry
and the institutional infrastructure are more function-
ally integrated into national or international innovation
systems, i.e. innovation activity takes place primarily
in co-operation with actors outside the region. Thus,
this represents a development model in which exoge-
nous actors and relationships play a larger role.

Cooke

(1998)

describes this type as ‘dirigiste RIS’, reflecting

a narrower definition of an innovation system incor-
porating mainly the R&D functions of universities,
research institutes and corporations. Second, the col-
laboration between organisations within this type of
RIS conforms more closely to the linear model, as
the co-operation primarily involves specific projects
to develop more radical innovations-based on formal
analytical-scientific knowledge. Within such systems,
co-operation is most likely to arise between people with
the same occupational or educational background (e.g.
among scientists). This functional similarity facilitates
the circulation and sharing of knowledge through ‘epis-

temic communities’, whose membership may cross
inter-regional and even international boundaries (

Amin

and Cohendet, 2003; Coenen et al., 2004

).

One special example of a regionalised national

innovation system is the clustering of R&D laboratories
of large firms and/or governmental research institutes
in planned ‘science parks’ and technopoles, normally
located in close proximity to universities and technical
colleges, but, according to evidence, typically having
limited linkages to local industry (

Asheim, 1995

). Sci-

ence parks are, thus, an example of a planned innovative
milieu comprised of firms with a high level of internal
resources and competence, situated within weak local
co-operative environments. These parks have generally
failed to develop innovative networks based on inter-
firm co-operation and interactive learning within the
science parks themselves (

Asheim and Cooke, 1998;

Henry et al., 1995

). Technopoles, as developed in

countries, such as France, Japan and Taiwan, are also
characterised by a limited degree of innovative inter-
action between firms within the pole, and by vertical
subcontracting relationships with non-local external
firms. In those rare cases where local innovative net-
works arise, they have normally been orchestrated by
deliberate public sector intervention at the national
level. These characteristics imply a lack of local and
regional embeddedness, and lead us to question the
capability of science parks and technopoles to pro-
mote innovativeness and competitiveness more widely
within local industries (especially SMEs) as a prereq-
uisite for endogenous regional development (

Asheim

and Cooke, 1998; Longhi and Qu´ere, 1993

).

To summarize, the main argument that this paper

puts forward is that there are different logics behind
constructing regional innovation systems contingent on
the knowledge base of the industry it addresses as well
as on the regional knowledge infrastructure which is
accessible. In a territorially embedded regional inno-
vation system, the emphasis lies on the localised, path-
dependent inter-firm learning processes often involving
innovation-based on synthetic knowledge. The role
of the regional knowledge infrastructure is therefore
mainly directed to industry-specific, hands-on services
and concrete, short-term problem solving, i.e. ex-post
support to the cluster. In a regionalised national innova-
tion system, R&D and scientific research take a much
more prominent position. Innovation builds primar-
ily on analytic knowledge. Linkages between existing

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1181

local industry and the knowledge infrastructure are,
however, weakly developed. Instead it holds the poten-
tial to promote new industries at the start of their indus-
trial and technological life cycle. In this, the role of
the regional(ized) knowledge infrastructure is a very
central one as it provides the cornerstone for clus-
ter development (through the precarious task of com-
mercialising science) and can thus be called ex-ante
cluster support. The regionally networked innovation
system can be considered as an ideal type RIS. Simi-
lar to the regionalised national innovation system, the
knowledge infrastructure plays an indispensible role.
But in contrast to it, the cluster is not science-driven
but market-driven. In comparison to the territorially
embedded regional innovation system, the networked
RIS often involves more advanced technologies com-
bining analytic and synthetic knowledge. While ter-
ritorially embedded RIS are often found in mature
industries and regionalised national innovation systems
found in emergent industries, networked regional inno-
vation systems are typically found in the growth phase
of an industry. Firms and knowledge infrastructure
form a dynamic ensemble, combining ex-post support
for incremental problem solving and ex-ante support to
counter technological and cognitive lock-ins. We shall
now draw our attention to five case studies to illus-
trate these different logics in the formation of regional
innovation systems.

5. Comparison of Nordic clusters

Below the difference between an ex-ante and ex-post

approach is illustrated on the basis of a comparative
analysis of five clusters in three Nordic countries: Den-
mark, Sweden and Norway

4

:

• The furniture cluster of Salling and the wireless com-

munication cluster of North Jutland in Denmark.

• The functional food ‘cluster’ of Scania in Sweden.

• The Rogaland food cluster and the Horten electron-

ics cluster in Norway.

On the issue of method

Cooke (1998, p. 12)

argues

that one of the distinct advantages of the RIS approach

4

These studies as such have been carried out by various researchers

through a joint research project called ‘Nordic SMEs and Regional
Innovation Systems’.

is that it allows for a systematic comparison of inno-
vation activities across various regions. “Conducting
such comparable studies can lead to identification of
some functional equivalents for specific as well as
generic problems within the innovation process”. How-
ever, various other researchers remain critical and argue
that the rise of the ‘Silicon Valley fever’ (

Benneworth

and Hardy, 2003

) has confined much work to text-book

cases in high-tech sectors (

Doloreux, 2002

). It is argued

that more attention should be paid to applying the
approach on other regions than the stereotypical ‘happy
few’ and, more importantly, theory must be informed
by the lessons drawn from such ordinary regions. This
critique resembles the arguably more narrow and rel-
atively static understanding of knowledge intensive
industries in the knowledge-based economy as opposed
to the broader scope applied in the learning economy
perspective. Providing an example of the latter per-
spective,

Kaufmann and T¨odtling (2000)

comparative

study of old traditional industrial regions shows that
the concept allows for utilisation in ordinary regions
and mature industries as well. The purpose of the case
studies in this paper is not to provide detailed and com-
prehensive accounts of the innovation systems in the
five regions. For this we refer to the original studies
(

Asheim et al., 2003b

). Instead we seek to substantiate

the arguments we made previously about the impor-
tance of the industrial knowledge base for the linkages
and support given in the context of the regional innova-
tion system by means of a comparative case analysis.
As such we choose to compare a set of clusters

5

that are

typically based on synthetic knowledge (Salling and
Rogaland) with clusters that have a stronger analytic
knowledge base component (North Jutland, Scania
and Horten). First a short introduction to the individ-
ual cases will be given followed by a more focused
discussion on the knowledge base of the respective
industries.

5.1. Introduction to the cases

In his study on the regional furniture industry in

and around the town of Salling in the North-West

5

Our selection of the cases is of course also predicated by their

inclusion in our joint research project ‘Nordic SMEs and Regional
Innovation Systems’ which applied a distinct case study oriented
approach to the different clusters that were studied.

background image

1182

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

of Jutland,

Lorenzen (2003)

reports on an extraordi-

nary economic growth over the past decades despite
high factors costs. Between 1972 and 1992 employ-
ment in the cluster tripled while overall employment
in Denmark decreased. The number of firms grew with
approximately 80%. In 1996, 2388 were employed in
54 firms, the majority of which are small and medium
sized. This performance is ascribed to the ability of
the cluster to collectively penetrate new markets, brand
products and develop new designs. This low-tech inno-
vativeness, which would run the risk of being ignored
in a knowledge-based economy perspective, is in turn
underpinned by a combination of stable and at the same
time flexible inter-firm relationships held together by
a high level of trust and shared norms and conventions
embedded in the local community of firm managers
and workers. The other Danish cluster located in North
Jutland is specialised in wireless communication and
located around the city of Aalborg. At present it con-
sists of roughly 35 firms employing around 3220 peo-
ple. In terms of firm size the cluster is composed of both
SMEs as well as establishments of major multination-
als. In 1997, the companies, Aalborg University and
the science park NOVI established the cluster associa-
tion NorCOM to formalize their co-operation (

Dalum

et al., 2002

).

It would go too far to consider the case of func-

tional foods in Scania an actual cluster as it consists
of only a handful of dedicated functional food firms
in and around the cities of Lund and Malm¨o. Yet it
could be suggested that a knowledge intensive embry-
onic cluster is taking shape under the wings of the
traditional food industry (

Holmberg, 2003

). Scania, in

the South of Sweden, has been a historically impor-
tant national centre for agricultural production (

Nilsson

et al., 2002

) and hosts some of the country’s largest

food processing industries. Functional food is defined
as artificially developed food with added ingredients
that demonstrate scientific evidence of positive health-
related effects. It is regarded as a novel technology with
high growth and innovation potentials in a traditionally
not very innovative industry. As such it provides a case
in point of the notion of distributed knowledge bases
by which the distinction between high-tech and low-
tech becomes increasingly blurred. Several small, R&D
intensive companies dedicated to functional food have
emerged around the University of Lund. These compa-
nies collaborate intensively with the traditional large

food companies for the actual production and market-
ing of functional foods as well as with regional research
groups and organisations for scientific research.

Rogaland, located in the South-West of Norway, is

one of the nation’s leading production areas in meat,
dairy foodstuffs, feed, shellfish and certain vegeta-
bles. In 1995, the region counted 161 firms manu-
facturing food and beverages (

Onsager, 1999

). These

employed approximately 4000 people. Several large
international companies are located here yet most firms
are small or medium sized.

Onsager and Aasen (2003)

distinguish three partly differentiated, partly integrated
subsystems: agrofood production, seafood production
and life-stock production. Even though each subsys-
tem exploits separate raw materials, production tech-
nologies and end markets, functional connections and
inter-relations across the subsystem are in place in con-
nection with subcontracting, common customers and
support organisations (R&D, training and professional
forums). Due to this agglomerated sector environment
a high degree of local collaboration underpins the
innovative efforts of the firms (

Onsager, 1999

). The

small electronics cluster in Horten in the South-East
of Norway, hosts around 25 firms and 1900 employees
(

Isaksen, 2003; Asheim and Isaksen, 2002

). The cluster

contains a few large enterprises but is otherwise dom-
inated by SMEs. The motive powers in the local elec-
tronics industry are the large system houses and orig-
inal equipment manufacturers (OEM)-suppliers which
originate mainly from the Norwegian national system
of innovation. At present, these firms still collaborate
mainly with national and international research organ-
isations, universities and customers in their innovative
activities. The cluster is held together by personal net-
works of individuals within different firms and impor-
tant knowledge transfer takes place through labour
mobility. In terms of industrial relationships the system
houses and OEM-suppliers have pronounced regional
linkages only with the local subcontractors in Horten.
As specialised producers of components and software
they play a significant role in innovation processes in
connection with transferring prototypes into effective
industrial production as well as for joint problem solv-
ing.

In the following section, we analyse the industrial

knowledge base of the respective clusters and their spe-
cific link with the region.

Table 2

summarizes the result

of our analysis.

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1183

T

able

2

Ov

ervie

w

o

f

Nordic

clusters

Number

of

firms

Emplo

yed

Kno

wledge

base

Re

gional

kno

wledge

infrastructure

Specific

re

gional

assets

Furniture,

Salling

54

2400

Synthetic

T

echnical

school

and

cabinetmak

ers

guild

Inter

-firm

relations

based

on

personal

netw

orks

and

local

culture

W

ireless

Communication,

North

Jutland

35

3220

Analytic

Aalbor

g

Uni

v

ersity

and

NO

VI

science

park

Close

link

between

firms

and

uni

v

ersity

,

highly

skilled

local

labour

force

Functional

food,

Scania

3

130

Analytic

Lund

Uni

v

ersity

Specialised

competence

at

Lund

Uni

v

ersity

(Functional

F

oods

Science

Centre)

F

ood,

Rogaland

161

4000

Synthetic

(Re

gionalised)

applied

R&D

o

rg

anisations

and

re

gional

de

v

elopment

or

ganisations

Ra

w

material

and

re

gional

netw

ork

Electronics,

Horten

25

1900

Analytic

and

synthetic

Only

recently

,

re

gional

uni

v

ersity

colle

ge

Personal

netw

ork

and

subcontractors

Sour

ces:

Dalum

et

al.

(2002)

,

Lorenzen

(2003)

,

Holmber

g

(2003)

,

Onsager

and

Aasen

(2003)

and

Isaksen

(2003)

.

5.2. Furniture cluster in Salling

The study by

Lorenzen (2003)

shows that in terms

of product innovations the furniture producing firms
in Salling mainly design varieties in for example style,
materials and colors based on the existing product-line.
Completely new products types are typically intro-
duced only once a year. Process innovations necessar-
ily follow such new product designs. The shift from
hardwood to other materials, notably plywood, is con-
sidered as the most dramatic shift that the cluster
witnessed. Experimentation at the factory floor and
product revision based upon employees’ ideas are key
mechanisms for the firms to innovate internally, illus-
trating very well the tacit and synthetic nature of the
knowledge base in the furniture industry. The primary
source of innovation are, however, interactive innova-
tion activities which take place through vertical net-
works between producers and their suppliers (in collab-
oration with existing suppliers or by reshuffling inputs
from other suppliers) and through horizontal networks
(e.g. matching product designs in order to offer fuller
product lines).

Lorenzen (2003)

highlights the impor-

tance of shared values and common norms among
managers within the firms to sustain these relation-
ships. Characteristic local conventions are craftsman-
ship, entrepreneurship, sense of belonging to an eco-
nomic community and local solidarity. It appears in fact
that in comparison with the localised cluster dynamics
the Salling firms have hardly any systematic learning
relationship with players outside the cluster. In addition
to the furniture firms themselves, two regional organi-
sations play an important role in sustaining the patterns
of localised inter-firm learning. Firstly, the workforce
often derives its initial training and necessary arti-
san skills from their education at the local technical
school. The school is considered as Denmark’s most
specialised educational institute for furniture produc-
tion and collaborates closely with the furniture firms
to align its curriculum with their needs. Secondly, the
local cabinetmakers’ guild provides a crucial venue to
regularly exchange information and co-ordinate inter-
firm relationships and to (re-)produce the conventions
embedding the firms to the Salling cluster. As such, the
firms in the cluster have become rooted in the region
through their mutual inter-dependence. Over the past
20 years each of the firms has developed its own ded-
icated niche through specialisation in specific parts

background image

1184

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

of the value chain in combination with an extensive
local network of stable yet flexible inter-firm relation-
ships allowing for economies of scope. The centrality
of localised learning based on synthetic knowledge in
this regional innovation system, the embeddedness of
the firms in a local economic community and the lim-
ited role of knowledge generating organisations make
a clear case for a territorially embedded RIS. Inno-
vation policy comes predominately in the form of
local ‘hands-on’ support for the existing structure of
the cluster and, thus, illustrates an ex-post approach
to constructing RIS (e.g. the local economic devel-
opment office’s help in attracting more trainees as
cabinetmakers).

5.3. Food cluster in Rogaland

For its competitiveness, the Rogaland cluster also

draws on a synthetic knowledge base mainly apply-
ing industry-specific technical knowledge. Typically
innovation takes place through constant improvements
of pre-existing product standards, packaging/design,
labelling, etc. (

Onsager and Aasen, 2003

). But differ-

ently from the Salling cluster, the region hosts impor-
tant food-related R&D bodies that are actively involved
in innovation activities with the companies. An exam-
ple is ‘Norconserv’ (the Norwegian Institute for Fish
Processing and Preservation Technology) which serves
as an important centre of expertise in adjustment and
development processes of production structures. Illus-
trating its systemic relationship with the local industry,
the ‘Norconserv’ institute is renowned for its hands-on
research actively tailored to the fish-producing indus-
try. Also the Norwegian School of Hotel Management
at the recently established University in Stavanger,
which is the only university-based education within
this area in the Nordic countries, has R&D programs in
place on economic and organisational issues relevant
to the industry. Many of the R&D bodies in Rogaland
are regionalised divisions of wider national organisa-
tions (e.g. the Norwegian Crop Research Institute) that
have been located in Rogaland because of the particular
agricultural and natural conditions that prevail in the
area. National R&D organisations outside Rogaland
(e.g. the Norwegian Institute for Fishery and Aquacul-
ture Research in Tromsø) are also of major importance
for the firms. As we will also see in the Horten case, the
traditional dominance of the national system of innova-

tion is characteristic for the Norwegian situation where
public R&D agencies (e.g. the Norwegian Research
Council) have a long tradition of designing R&D pro-
grammes at the national level. Nonetheless, recent
policy measures are moving towards stronger regional-
isation tendencies providing more targeted innovation
support that is more closely aligned to the needs of
the industry in place. The regional development pro-
gram Arena for Regional Commercial Development
and Entrepreneurship (ARNE) in which the private
sector, municipal and regional authorities co-operate
to support the food industry (through projects on, e.g.
ecological food and micro algae) can be seen as an
example of this. An important network organisation
for the Rogaland cluster is the ‘Fagforum for Mat
og Drikke’ (Professional Forum for Food and Drink)
whose primary mission is to promote knowledge shar-
ing and competence dissemination among local firms,
education and R&D organisations. Current efforts are
directed to open ‘The House of Food’ as a regional
centre of expertise on gastronomy and food technol-
ogy. Based on broad participation of the players in
the cluster it aims to become a one stop shop for
companies wishing to initiate product development
programs. As we can see, this cluster is typically depen-
dent on both the regional and national level for its
innovation support. Because of natural conditions as
well as the historical agglomeration of agriculture and
food industry in the area, relevant R&D and educa-
tional organisations have been directed to the Roga-
land region. However, this had more of a top-down
character in which R&D programs were designed at
the national level. Current innovation support is more
directly and explicitly aligned to regional needs and can
be regarded as ex-post innovation support to the cluster.
In comparison to Salling, this cluster is more depen-
dent on the knowledge infrastructure (albeit heavily
applied) provided by universities and research insti-
tutes (on national and regional level). Given current
efforts to increasingly regionalise innovation support
(endorsed by the national government) it can thus be
regarded as a networked regional innovation system.
Similar to the Scania case, this case illustrates very well
how systemic innovation interaction between firms and
the knowledge infrastructure is based on a distributed
knowledge base. Typical for Rogaland is, however, the
wide-spectre of innovation support for the food sec-
tor, most of the time involving synthetic knowledge

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1185

though sometimes innovation based on analytic knowl-
edge can be observed (e.g. research on functional
foods).

5.4. Wireless communication cluster in Northern
Jutland

The above cases of low-tech innovations can be

contrasted with the wireless communication cluster of
Northern Jutland and the embryonic functional food
cluster in Scania. These cases are exemplars of ana-
lytic knowledge base clusters for which the regional
knowledge infrastructure has played a crucial and fun-
damental role right from the start of the cluster. The his-
torical overview of the wireless communication cluster
in North Jutland by

Dalum et al. (1999, 2002)

shows

clearly how the presence of Aalborg university and the
NOVI science park have been essential fundaments for
the cluster’s establishment and growth. A real break-
through came about through the university’s establish-
ment in 1974. The regional supply of highly skilled
engineers equipped with much needed competences in
the field of wireless communications has been a pre-
requisite for the growth of the local industry. In combi-
nation with the university’s research orientation in this
field (“basic research with a sufficiently application-
oriented touch” (p. 16)) this constitutes a core asset of
the region attracting major multinational companies.
Also the success of the NOVI science park demon-
strates the systemic interaction between firms and uni-
versity in and around Aalborg. The regional innovation
system presented in this case is also of the regionally
networked type. It distinguishes itself from a region-
alised national innovation system by a characteristic
regional embedding through localised inter-firm learn-
ing as well as systemic regional industry–university
interaction which the latter typically is lacking. In
this context, Aalborg university should be seen as a
real cornerstone for the cluster. Without it, the cluster
would not have developed its distinctive competence
and technological excellence in wireless communi-
cation on which the competitiveness of the cluster
builds. As such it illustrates the ex-ante approach to
constructing regional innovation systems as the logic
behind innovation support has been more inclined to
establishing new economic activities based on a break-
through technology rather than to support an existing
industrial specialisation. Moreover, it could be argued

that the role of a skilled workforce (consisting of
researchers and engineers) plays a more important role
as a link between the knowledge infrastructure and
the firms than in the two preceding clusters based on
a synthetic knowledge base. Even though the knowl-
edge base of the cluster is mainly analytic given the
prominence of state-of-the-art scientific achievement,
it should be noted that it has proceeded further along
its technological life-cycle compared to functional
foods.

5.5. Functional food ‘cluster’ in Scamia

A fairly similar account can be given for the func-

tional foods ‘cluster’ in Scania yet on a more mod-
erate scale in terms of companies (

Holmberg, 2003

).

In line with findings for the Swedish biotechnology-
pharmaceutical sector (

McKelvey et al., 2003

) inter-

firm knowledge linkages between the small, dedicated
research firms are relatively weak despite being colo-
cated. Instead, the firms are involved in collabora-
tive research with companies and research organisa-
tions on all geographical levels. Notwithstanding this,
Lund University has been of crucial importance for
the establishment of the functional food companies
as it provided the seedbed for the original scientific
ideas underpinning these firms. But also on an on-
going basis the presence of world-class research and
education facilities in the field of functional foods
serves as a conduit to cutting-edge science for the func-
tional food firms. This has been further reinforced by
the recent establishment of the cross-faculty research
centre Functional Foods Science Centre which is one
of the flagship projects supported by the ‘Vinnv¨axt’
program of the Swedish public agency for innova-
tion systems, VINNOVA, to promote the formation
of regional innovation systems. In this, similar to the
wireless communication case, human capital is high-
lighted as an asset which needs to be capitalized. Also
here we see an illustration of the ex-ante approach
which takes it vantage point in the knowledge infras-
tructure because of the relative novelty of functional
foods. Nonetheless, the future of functional foods will
depend strongly on whether the traditional food sec-
tor in Scania and consumers will endorse it. There-
fore, it would be most appropriate to characterise this
case as a networked regional innovation system ‘under
construction’.

background image

1186

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

5.6. Electronics cluster in Horten

Right from the beginning in the 1960s, the pioneer-

ing firms of the Horten electronics cluster have had
knowledge linkages mainly connecting into the Norwe-
gian national system of innovation. These firms were
in fact spin-offs from important national knowledge
organisations (e.g. the Norwegian Technical University
in Trondheim) and were established based on product
ideas that originated there. Also later on, the (radi-
cal) product development mainly drew on co-operation
with technological R&D institutes and large public and
private clients in Norway and abroad, and in projects
often partly financed by the Norwegian Research Coun-
cil (

Isaksen, 2003

). Similar to the Rogaland case, this

should be conceived through the Norwegian tradition
for nation based R&D programs. In contrast to Roga-
land, the regional knowledge infrastructure was of little
value for the electronics cluster. For the technologi-
cally advanced system houses and OEM-suppliers this
is nowadays still the case. According to

Isaksen (2003)

these companies have even grown out of the national
innovation system that they rose from and are increas-
ingly collaborating on an international level with firms
and R&D institutes. What ties these firms then to
Horten? This stickiness should be understood through
the build up of unique competences among key per-
sonnel attached to the locality (

Asheim and Isaksen,

2002

). Furthermore, the role of local subcontractors

appears to be important. These have started their busi-
ness since the beginning of the 1980s after the system
firms closed down their in-house production facilities.
While the knowledge-base of the system houses and
OEM suppliers tends to be more inclined to an analyti-
cal knowledge base, innovation activities of these local
subcontractors typically build on a synthetic knowl-
edge base. Even if the growth of a regional university
college has modified this picture somewhat in the last
years, the RIS in this region must still be characterised
as a regionalised national innovation system. Thus, at
the start of the cluster, regional innovation support was
more or less lacking. Ex-ante support, for example,
through collaborative research projects financed by the
Norwegian Research Council, was embedded outside
the region. At present the level of technological sophis-
tication and specialisation is high which makes it hard
to construct or adjust a regional innovation system fit-
ting the needs of the system houses and OEM suppliers.

Instead current policy efforts are mainly targeted at
local subcontractors in order to keep this cluster tied to
the region through local network building. An example
of this ex-post approach is the exchange of production
workers between local firms and training of managers
supported through the RIS program ‘REGINN’ of the
Norwegian Research Council.

6. Conclusions

In this paper, we have made the argument that in a

learning economy clusters and RIS need to be treated
as two different yet strongly inter-related concepts. The
cluster concept is substantially narrower than the RIS
concept because of the strong sectoral connotation in
clusters whereas a regional innovation system can tran-
scend multiple sectors. Also from a policy perspective
it is important to keep this distinction in mind due to the
difference in sector specificity versus genericness. Fur-
thermore we analysed the relationship between indus-
tries and RIS from an industrial knowledge base per-
spective on the basis of a comparison of Nordic clusters
where we differentiated between an ex-ante and ex-
post approach to constructing regional innovation sys-
tems. For industries drawing on a analytic knowledge
base, a sophisticated and aligned knowledge infras-
tructure is indispensable to embed the industry in the
region. Key mechanisms in this are the local supply of
high-skilled labour and access to scientific excellence.
Therefore, RIS policy should address the regional pro-
vision of such a knowledge infrastructure as well as
systemic regional university–industry interaction. If
such a knowledge infrastructure is in place at the
start of the cluster’s life-cycle (i.e. ex-ante approach)
it facilitates co-ordination within the system thereby
increasing the potential for a networked regional inno-
vation system rather than a regionalised national one.
For industries drawing on a synthetic knowledge base,
inter-firm localised learning plays an important role.
It is essential that innovation policy recognises this. It
also implies that support from a regional knowledge
infrastructure needs to be aligned to the already exist-
ing industrial specialisation (i.e. ex-post approach). In
other words, it should be demand-led. The presence of
such a tuned-in, hands-on support infrastructure makes
the difference between a territorially embedded and a
networked regional innovation system.

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1187

This brings us to the final point in this paper which

is that of the regionalisation of innovation policy and
the rationale from a policy point of view to apply the
RIS concept. A set of variations on the systems of
innovation approach have been developed over time,
either taking territories as their point of departure
(national and regional) or specific sectors or technolo-
gies (

Fagerberg et al., 2004

). The regional innovation

system concept was inspired by the national innovation
system concept, and it is based on a similar rationale
that emphasizes territorially based innovation systems.
It can, however, be argued that the national innovation
systems perspective is still faced with difficulties to
draw the boundaries of the system and to define its ele-
ments (

Edquist, 1997

). With regard to these aspects,

Lundvall (1999)

admits that, for example, studies on

national business systems (

Whitley, 1999

) have been

more explicit and consistent in their selection of the
system’s organisations and institutions. Therefore, it is
important to emphasize the connotation of innovation
networks (

Kaufmann and T¨odtling, 2001

) rather than

systems in a Luhmanian social system approach as they
tend to ‘over-abstract’ the substantial and material con-
tent of innovative interaction (

Miettinen, 2002

).

Characteristic for a systems approach to innova-

tion is, thus, the acknowledgement that innovations are
carried out through a network of various actors under-
pinned by an institutional framework. On the national
level, this system is in most cases very large, complex
and involving a plethora of linkages. Because of the
high level of aggregation it remains difficult to pro-
vide a level of empirical groundedness instrumental
for innovation policy development.

Miettinen (2002)

argues that principles of historicity, industry specificity
and region specificity need to be taken into consider-
ation to arrive at less abstract and more disaggregated
‘reduced-form innovation systems’. Also

Lundvall and

Borras (1997)

hint towards this when they argue that

“the region is increasingly the level at which innova-
tion is produced through regional networks of innova-
tors, local clusters and the cross-fertilising effects of
research institutions” (p. 39).

The case studies presented in the previous section

illustrate how studies of regional innovation systems
provide concrete, policy-relevant analysis making vis-
ible the interplay between various actors, the contri-
butions of different institutions and the relevance of
regional and national policy measures. Regional inno-

vation policy should, however, not be formulated based
on off-the-shelf, ‘best-practice’ solutions drawn “from
the experience of successful regions or some expert
manual” (

Amin, 1999

, p. 371). But through the region-

alisation of innovation policy more accurate consider-
ation can be paid to the region’s specific context and
circumstances in terms of the industrial structure, insti-
tutional set-up and knowledge base. Thus, it contains
the potential for innovation policy to be more focused
by providing support that is needed given the demands
generated by industrial specificities. In this the distinc-
tion between analytical and synthetic knowledge and
its important consequences for innovation policy are
an example of such sharper focus that can be catered
for at the regional level. Notwithstanding this, region-
alisation should not be understood as regionalism by
neglecting the embeddedness of regions in a national
and trans-national framework.

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of this paper has benefited from

being presented at the ‘Regionalization of Innovation
Policy’ conference, organised by the German Institute
for Economic Research (DIW Berlin) on June 4–5,
2004, in Berlin and at the 2004 DRUID Summer con-
ference ‘Industrial Dynamics, Innovation and Devel-
opment’ on June 14–16 in Helsing¨or, Denmark. The
authors thank the participants in the project ‘Nordic
SMEs and Regional Innovation Systems’ for their valu-
able contributions. Special thanks go to the guest edi-
tors Michael Fritsch and Andreas Stephan as well as
five anonymous referees. Acknowledgement is given
to the Nordic Innovation Centre and KUNI, the Nor-
wegian Research Council, for their financial support.

References

Amin, A., 1999. An institutionalist perspective on regional eco-

nomic development. International Journal of Urban and Regional
Research 23 (2), 365–378.

Amin, A., Cohendet, P., 2003. Architectures of Knowledge. Oxford

University Press, Oxford.

Asheim, B.T., 1995. Regionale Innovasjonssystem—en Sosialt

og

Territorielt

Forankret

Teknologipolitikk.

Nordisk

Samh¨allsgeografisk Tidskrift 20, 17–34.

background image

1188

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

Asheim, B.T., 1998. Territoriality and economics: on the substantial

contribution of economic geography. In: Jonsson, O., Olander,
L.-O. (Eds.), Economic Geography in Transition, vol. 74. The
Swedish Geographical Yearbook, Lund, pp. 98–109.

Asheim, B.T., 1999. Interactive learning and localised knowledge

in globalising learning economies. GeoJournal 49 (4), 345–
352.

Asheim, B.T., 2000. Industrial districts: the contributions of mar-

shall and beyond. In: Clark, G.L., Feldman, M.P., Gertler, M.S.
(Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford
University Press, Oxford, pp. 413–431.

Asheim, B.T., 2001. Learning regions as development coalitions:

partnership as governance in european workfare states? Concepts
and Transformations: International Journal of Action Research
and Organizational Renewal 6 (1), 73–101.

Asheim, B.T., 2002. Temporary organisations and spatial embedded-

ness of learning and knowledge creation. Geografiska Annaler:
Series B Human Geography 84, 111–124.

Asheim, B.T., Cooke, P., 1998. Localised Innovation Networks in

a Global Economy: A Comparative Analysis of Endogenous
and Exogenous Regional Development Approaches. Compar-
ative Social Research 17, JAI Press, Stamford, CT, pp. 199–
240.

Asheim, B.T., Cooke, P., 1999. Local learning and interactive

innovation networks in a global economy. In: Malecki, E.,
Oinas, P. (Eds.), Making Connections: Technological Learning
and Regional Economic Change. Ashgate, Aldershot, pp. 145–
178.

Asheim, B.T., Gertler, M.S., 2005. The geography of innovation:

regional innovation systems. In: Fagerberg, J., Mowery, D., Nel-
son, R. (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Innovation. Oxford
University Press, Oxford, pp. 291–317.

Asheim, B.T., Herstad, S.J., 2003. Regional innovation systems, vari-

eties of capitalism and non-local relations: challenges from the
globalising economy. In: Asheim, B.T., Mariussen, ˚

A. (Eds.),

Innovations, Regions and Projects, vol. 3. Nordregio, Stockholm,
pp. 241–274.

Asheim, B.T., Isaksen, A., 2002. Regional innovation systems: the

integration of local ‘sticky’ and global ‘ubiquitous’ knowledge.
Journal of Technology Transfer 27, 77–86.

Asheim, B.T., et al. (Eds.), 2003a. Regional Innovation Policy for

Small-Medium Enterprises. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

Asheim, B.T., Coenen, L., Svensson-Henning, M., 2003b. Nordic

SMEs and Regional Innovation Systems—Final Report. Nordic
Industrial Fund, Oslo (

http://www.nordicinnovation.net

).

Bathelt, H., 2003. Geographies of production: growth regimes in spa-

tial perspectives 1—innovation, institutions and social systems.
Progress in Human Geography 27 (6), 789–804.

Bathelt, H., 2005.Geographies of production: growth regimes in spa-

tial perspectives (II) knowledge creation and growth in clusters.
Progress in Human Geography 29 (2), 204–216.

Bathelt, H., Malmberg, A., Maskell, P., 2004. Clusters and knowl-

edge: local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowledge
creation. Progress in Human Geography 28 (1), 31–56.

Benneworth, P., Hardy, S., 2003. In Celebration of the ‘Ordinary’

Region. In: Introduction to paper session at the RGS-IBG Inter-
national Annual Conference, September 3–5, London.

Carlsson, B., 2004. Innovation systems: a survey of the literature

from a schumpeterian perspective. In: Pycka, A. (Ed.), The
Companion to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham.

Coenen, L., Moodysson, J., Asheim, B.T., 2004. Nodes, networks

and proximities: on the knowledge dynamics of the medicon val-
ley biotech cluster. European Planning Studies 12 (7), 1003–
1018.

Cooke, P., 1998. Introduction: origins of the concept. In: Braczyk, H.,

Cooke, P., Heidenreich, M. (Eds.), Regional Innovation Systems,
first ed. UCL Press, London, pp. 2–25.

Cooke, P., 2004. Evolution of regional innovation systems—

emergence, theory, challenge for action. In: Cooke, P., et al.
(Eds.), Regional Innovation Systems, second ed. Routledge, Lon-
don, pp. 1–18.

Cooke, P. Regional innovation systems, asymmetric knowledge and

the legacies of learning. In: Rutten, et al. (Ed.), The Learning
Region: Foundations, State of the Art, Future. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, in press.

Cooke, P., Leydesdorff, L. Regional development in the knowledge-

based economy: the construction of advantage. Journal of Tech-
nology Transfer, in press.

Cooke, P., Morgan, K., 1998. The Associational Economy: Firms,

Regions and Innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Cooke, P., Boekholt, P., T¨odtling, F., 2000. The governance of inno-

vation in europe. In: Regional Perspectives on Global Competi-
tiveness. Pinter, London.

Cooke, P., Heidenreich, M., Braczyk, H.-J. (Eds.), 2004. Regional

Innovation Systems, second ed. Routledge, London.

Cooke, P., Uranga, M.G., Etxebarria, G., 1998. Regional systems of

innovation: an evolutionary perspective. Environment and Plan-
ning A 30, 1563–1584.

Dalum, B., et al., 1999. The formation of knowledge-based clusters

in north jutland and western sweden. In: Paper presented at the
DRUID Conference on National Innovation Systems, Industrial
Dynamics and Innovation Policy, June 9–12, Rebild.

Dalum, B., Pedersen C., Villumsen, G., 2002. Technological life

cycles: regional clusters facing disruption. DRUID Working
Paper 02-10. Aalborg University, Aalborg.

Doloreux, D., 2002. What we should know about regional systems

of innovation. Technology in Society 24, 243–263.

Edquist, C., 1997. Introduction. In: Edquist, C. (Ed.), Systems of

Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organisations. Pinter,
London.

Etzkowitz, H., Leydesdorff, L., 2000. The dynamics of innova-

tion: from national systems and ‘Mode 2’ to a Triple Helix of
University–industry–government relations. Research Policy 29,
109–123.

Fagerberg, J., Mowery, D., Nelson, R. (Eds.), 2004. The

Oxford Handbook of Innovation. Oxford University Press,
Oxford.

Freeman, C., October 1993. The political economy of the long

wave. In: Paper Presented at EAPE 1993 Conference on ‘The
Economy of the Future: Ecology, Technology, Institutions’,
Barcelona.

Gertler, M., 2004. Manufacturing Culture: The Institutional Geogra-

phy of Industrial Practice. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

background image

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

1189

Granovetter, M., 1985. Economic action and social structure: the

problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 91,
481–510.

Hall, P., Soskice, D., 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institu-

tional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford Univer-
sity Press, Oxford.

Henry, N., et al., 1995. Along the road: R&D, society and space.

Research Policy 24, 707–726.

Hirsch-Kreinsen, H., Jacobson, D., Laestadius, S., Smith, K.,

2003. Low-Tech Industries and the Knowledge Economy: State
of the Art and Research Challenges. STEP Report 16-2003,
Oslo.

Holmberg, G., 2003. Functional foods in Scania, Sweden. In:

Asheim, B.T., Coenen, L., Svensson-Henning, M. (Eds.), Nordic
SMEs and Regional Innovation Systems—Final Report. Nordic
Industrial Fund, Oslo (

http://www.nordicinnovation.net

).

Howells, J., 1999. Regional systems of innovation? In: Archibugi, D.,

et al. (Eds.), Innovation Policy in a Global Economy. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge.

Isaksen, A. (Ed.), 1999. Regionale Innovasjonssystemer: Innovasjon

og Læring i 10 Regionale Næringsmiljøer. STEP Report 02-1999,
Oslo.

Isaksen, A., 2003. Learning, globalization, and the electronics cluster

in horten: discussing the local buzz—global pipeline argument.
In: Asheim, B.T., Coenen, L., Svensson-Henning, M. (Eds.),
Nordic SMEs and Regional Innovation Systems—Final Report.
Nordic Industrial Fund, Oslo (

http://www.nordicinnovation.net

).

Isaksen, A., 2005. Regional clusters building on local and non-

local relationships: a European comparison. In: Lagendijk, A.,
Oinas, P. (Eds.), Proximity, Distance and Diversity: Issues on
Economic Interaction and Local Development. Ashgate, Alder-
shot, pp. 129–152.

Isaksen, A., Hauge, E., 2002. Regional Clusters in Europe. Observa-

tory of European SMEs report 2002 No. 3, European Communi-
ties, Luxembourg.

Johnson, B., Lundvall, B.- ˚

A., 2001. Why all this fuss about

codified and tacit knowledge? In: Paper presented at the
DRUID ACADEMY Winter Conference, Korsør, January 18–
20.

Kaufmann, A., T¨odtling, F., 2000. Systems of innovation in tra-

ditional industrial regions: the case of styria in a comparative
perspective. Regional Studies 34 (1), 29–40.

Kaufmann, A., T¨odtling, F., 2001. Science–industry interaction in

the process of innovation: the importance of boundary-crossing
between systems. Research Policy 30, 791–804.

Laestadius, S., 1998. Technology level, knowledge formation and

industrial competence in paper manufacturing. In: Eliasson, G.,
et al. (Eds.), Micro Foundations of Economic Growth. The Uni-
versity of Michigan Press, Ann Arbour, pp. 212–226.

Longhi, C., Qu´ere, M., 1993. Innovative networks and the technop-

olis phenomenon: the case of sophie-antipolis. Environment and
Planning C: Goverment and Policy 11, 317–330.

Lorenzen, M., 2003. Low-Tech localized learning: the regional inno-

vation system of salling, denmark. In: Asheim, B.T., Coenen,
L., Svensson-Henning, M. (Eds.), Nordic SMEs and Regional
Innovation Systems—Final Report. Nordic Industrial Fund, Oslo
(

http://www.nordicinnovation.net

).

Lundvall, B.- ˚

A. (Ed.), 1992. National Systems of Innovation:

Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. Pinter,
London.

Lundvall, B.- ˚

A., 1999. National business systems and national sys-

tems of innovation. International Studies of Management &
Organisation 29 (2), 60–77.

Lundvall, B- ˚

A., Archibugi, D. (Eds.), 2001. The Globalizing Learn-

ing Economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Lundvall, B.- ˚

A., Borras, S., 1997. The Globalising Learning Econ-

omy: Implications for Innovation Policy. European Communi-
ties, Luxembourg.

Maskell, P., Eskelinen, H., Hannibalsson, L., Malmberg, A., Vatne,

E., 1998. Competitiveness, Localised Learning and Regional
Development. Routeledge, London.

McKelvey, M., Alm, H., Riccaboni, A., 2003. Does co-location

matter for formal knowledge collaboration in the swedish
biotechnology-pharmaceutical sector? Research Policy 32 (3),
483–501.

Miettinen, R., 2002. National Innovation System: Scientific Concept

or Political Rhetoric. Edita, Helsinki.

Moulaert, F., Sekia, F., 2003. Territorial Innovation models: a critical

survey. Regional Studies 37 (3), 289–302.

Nonaka, I., Reinm¨oller, P., 1998. The legacy of learning: toward

endogenous knowledge creation for Asian economic develop-
ment. WZB Jahrbuch 1998, 401–433.

Nonaka, et al., 2000. SECI, Ba and leadership: a unified model

of dynamic knowledge creation. Long Range Planning 33, 5–
34.

Nilsson, M., Svensson-Henning, M., Wilkenson, O., 2002. Sk˚anska

Kluster och Profilomr˚aden—En Kritisk Granskning. Region
Sk˚ane, Malm¨o.

OECD, 1986. OECD Science and Technology Indicators, R&D,

Innovation and Competitiveness. OECD, Paris.

OECD, 1996. The Knowledge-Based Economy. OECD, Paris.
Onsager, K., 1999. Matindustrien i Innovative Nettverk i Roga-

land. In: Isaksen, A. (Ed.), Regionale Innovasjonssystemer: Inno-
vasjon og Læring i 10 Regionale Næringsmiljøer. Step Rapport
2-1999, Oslo.

Onsager, K., Aasen, B., 2003. The Case of “Rogaland Regional

Food Cluster”. In: Asheim, B.T., Coenen, L., Svensson-
Henning, M. (Eds.), Nordic SMEs and Regional Innova-
tion Systems—Final Report. Nordic Industrial Fund, Oslo
(

http://www.nordicinnovation.net

).

Pavitt, K., 1984. Sectoral Patterns of technical change: towards a

taxonomy and a theory. Research policy 13, 343–373.

Porter, M.E., 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Billing

and Sons Ltd., Worchester.

Porter, M.E., 2000. Locations, clusters and company strategy. In:

Clark, G.L., Feldman, M.P., Gertler, M.S. (Eds.), The Oxford
Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford University Press,
Oxford, pp. 253–274.

Saxenian, A., 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition

in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press, Cam-
bridge, Massachusetts.

Smith, K., 2000. What is ‘The Knowledge Economy’? Knowledge-

intensive Industries and Distributed Knowledge Bases. Paper
presented at the DRUID Summer Conference on ‘The Learn-

background image

1190

B.T. Asheim, L. Coenen / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1173–1190

ing Economy—Firms, Regions and Nation Specific Institutions’,
Aalborg, Denmark, June 2000.

Storper, M., Scott, A., 1995. The Wealth of Regions. Futures 27 (5),

505–526.

T¨odtling, F., Trippl, M., 2005. Networking and project organisation

in the Styrian automotive industry. In: Lagendijk, A., Oinas,

P. (Eds.), Proximity, Distance and Diversity: Issues on Eco-
nomic Interaction and Local Development, Ashgate, Aldershot,
pp. 89–110.

Whitley, R., 1999. Divergent Capitalisms—the Social Structuring

and Change of Business Systems. Oxford University Press,
Oxford.


Document Outline


Wyszukiwarka

Podobne podstrony:
S Forgan Building the Museum Knowledge, Conflict and the Power of Place (w) Isis, vol 96, No 4 (XI
2005 6 NOV Rehabilitation and Physical Therapy
countries and regions
Knowledge Possibility and Consciousness Apr 2001
Communities of Knowledge Teaching and Learning
Banking structure and Regional Economic Growth lessons from Italy
Peng, Ames, Knowles Culture and Human Inference
Sobczyński, Marek Achievements of the Department of Political Geography and Regional Studies, Unive
The interaction between knowledge codification and knowledge sharing
John Perry Knowledge, Possibility, and Consciousness notes
Farina Reproduction of auditorium spatial impression with binaural and stereophonic sound systems
Filtration and Air Cleaning Systems
Tworzenie i wdrażanie regionalnych strategii i systemów innowacji w Polsce
M39t1 Remote Keyless Entry and Anti theft System
M39t2 Remote Keyless Entry and Anti theft System
DIALOG Polish and British political system docx
[0] Step Motor And Servo Motor Systems And Controls
EV (Electric Vehicle) and Hybrid Drive Systems

więcej podobnych podstron