CEIS Tor Vergata
RESEARCH PAPER SERIES
Vol. 6, Issue 5, No. 118 – March 2008
Bank Shareholding and Lending: Complementary
or Substitution? Some Evidence from a Panel of
Large Italian Firms
Emilio Barucci and Fabrizio Mattesini
Bank shareholding and lending: complementarity or
substitution? Some evidence from a panel of large Italian
firms
∗
Emilio Barucci* and Fabrizio Mattesini**
*Politecnico di Milano
Dipartimento di Matematica
Via Bonardi 9, 20133 Milan, Italy
**Universit´
a di Roma “Tor Vergata”
Dipartimento di Economia e Istituzioni
Via Columbia 2, 00133 Rome, Italy
January 10, 2008
Abstract
The paper studies the motivations behind banks’ shareholding of non-financial
firms using a panel of large Italian companies in the period 1994-2000. Empirical
evidence shows that banks are shareholders of companies that are less profitable,
have experienced slower growth, are more indebted and are endowed with collateral
and have hard time to repay their debt out of current income. Banks are more
likely to hold shares in companies they lend to. Overall the evidence suggests that
there is complementarity between bank equity holding and lending. A plausible
explanation is the shareholder-debtholder conflict, the evidence is weakly compatible
with governance and information hypotheses.
Keywords: Lending, cross shareholding, conflict of interest.
JeL classification: G21, G24.
∗
We thank Bob Chirinko and two anonymous referees for useful comments. The usual disclaimers
apply.
1
1
Introduction
Economists have long debated the reasons behind various types of bank-firm relation-
ships and their effects on firm performance. The debate has concentrated mainly on the
dichotomy between Anglo-Saxon type, market centered systems, where banks are rela-
tively unimportant and have arms’ length relationships with firms, and German-Japanese
bank centered systems where banks are allowed to invest directly in non-financial com-
panies, and companies are often related to a bank through exclusive relationships, the
so called main bank liaison. Other systems which fall between these two extremes have
been subject to less intense scrutiny. During the 1990s, however, a pervasive financial
deregulation around the world has taken place, giving rise to important reforms, such as
the Second Directive on Banking of 1993 in the European Union and the Gramm-Leach-
Biley Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999 in the US. Thanks to these pieces of
legislation, the gap between these two systems has closed significantly. Many restrictions
on bank ownership of equity in non financial firms have been removed in the US and in
many European countries, and this has rendered the issue of banks’ involvement in the
capital of non financial firms quite relevant also in systems traditionally characterized
by a strict separation between banks and firms
1
.
In this respect the Italian case is quite interesting. Even though the Italian system
can be defined as a ”bank based” system where banks play a central role in firms’ external
financing and security markets are relatively underdeveloped, traditionally the Italian
financial market has been characterized by arms’ length banking relationships and by
a rigid separation between commercial and investment banking
2
. These characteristics
developed as the result of the dramatic regulatory changes induced by the banking law
of 1936, which was approved as a response to the collapse of the large ”German type”
1
The financial deregulation on bank-non financial companies relationship occurred during the 1990s
was probably motivated by the positive governance effect associated with bank shareholding in Germany
and Japan as detected at that time, for empirical evidence see [Gorton and Schmid, 2000, Flath, 1993,
Prowse, 1992].
2
For
a
characterization
of
the
Italian
financial
system
see
[Cobham, Cosci and Mattesini, 1999].
2
universal banks and the subsequent rescue by the Italian State. This crisis was largely
the consequence of the enormous equity stake that these banks had acquired on the major
Italian corporations. During the 1990s, however, the regulatory framework was radically
reformed. Banks were transformed into joint stock companies and then privatized, bank
branching was liberalized and the Bank of Italy adopted a system of ”prudential” (as
opposed to ”structural”) supervision. Among these provisions there was a significant
removal of restrictions on banks’ investment in non-financial firms. This important
change occurred with the approval in 1994 of the Uniform Banking Code (Testo Unico
Bancario) which introduced in the Italian legislation the norms contained in the Second
EU Directive on banking, designed to encourage the transformation of European banks
into universal banks. According to the new code, banks are allowed to invest up to
15% of their capital in the capital of non financial firms and up to 3% of their capital
in a single firm; the Bank of Italy has the power to relax these limits for banks with a
large capital or that specialize in long term activities, or in case of restructuring of firms
with financial difficulties. These limits are much more restrictive than those imposed by
the Second EU directive but represent, nevertheless, a significant novelty relative to the
previous situation.
3
The new regulation allows banks to play a crucial role in the Italian financial mar-
ket. Due to the short period elapsed, it is difficult to obtain a very clear assessment of
the evolution of the Italian financial system. If we measure the role of financial insti-
tutions through the financial intermediation ratio,
4
we observe that the ratio in Italy
has increased during the last ten years (from 0.34 in 1995 to 0.38 in 2004), but if we
restrict the ratio to bank assets we see that it has remained constant around 0.27 (see
[Banca d’Italia, 2006] and [Bartirolo and De Bonis, 2005]) remaining at an intermediate
3
The directive simply establishes that a bank cannot invest more than 60% of its capital in
shares of non-financial firms and sets at 15% of a bank’s capital the ceiling on the acquisition by
a bank of shares of any single non-financial company.
4
The financial intermediation ratio is defined as the ratio of assets held by financial corporations (the
central bank, banks, other financial intermediaries, insurance corporations and pension funds) over total
assets.
3
level between the one of Germany (0.37) and that of the US (0.14). This seems to in-
dicate that in Italy banks have interpreted the opportunities offered by the new system
by enlarging their business towards non traditional banking services (asset management-
bancaassurance). However, if we look at bank equity holdings, we can detect a significant
increase in the last few years. While in 1998 banks owned about 3 billion euros of shares
of non financial firms (excluding the companies offering direct services to banks), in 2006
banks’ equity holding amounted to more than 8.3 billion.
To assess the effect of the new regulation, we turn to the micro level and we analyze
the rationale behind Italian banks’ equity investments in non-financial firms
5
. The aim
is twofold. First, we provide new evidence on bank-firm cross-shareholding in a context
which is quite different from those usually analyzed in the literature i.e., a system where
banks do not tend to act as ”main banks” with respect to companies as in Germany and
Japan and a system that is also quite different from the Anglo-Saxon model. Second,
we evaluate what is the rationale behind banks’ holding equity in non-financial firms in
relation to the traditional activity of banks, i.e. that of providing credit to firms. In
particular, we ask whether there is complementarity between bank shareholding and bank
lending and we try, with the available data, to provide some interpretation of the nature
of this relationship. The issue is quite important because bank-equity relationships
may be crucial in determining the health of a country’s financial system. Some recent
evidence on cross shareholding and relationship banking in Japan, for example, shows
that this phenomenon has been quite negative, being responsible for some of the problems
that have affected the Japanese financial system in the nineties.
6
This stands in clear
contrast with the literature developed in the eighties and in the nineties which viewed
the involvement of banks in non-financial firms as a strength of the Japanese financial
5
Due to the short period of time elapsed from bank shareholding liberalization, the evidence on the
Italian financial market is rather limited. [Bianco and Chiri, 1997] analyzing bank shareholding by the
end of 1996 show that only 20% of the total banks equity holdings of non-financial companies is due to
pure investment, while the vast majority of equity shareholding seems to be due to debt restructuring.
6
Note that Italy and Japan share a weak degree of creditor protection, see [La Porta et al., 1998],
and banks may be interested in detaining a stake to ensure debt repayment.
4
system.
We analyze a panel of the largest Italian non financial companies (listed and not
listed) considering data on balance sheets, ownership structure and detailed information
on firms’ long term debt relationships. The dataset is unique because we have information
on specific bank-company equity and lending relationships, and this allows us to look at
the interplay between lending and banks’ holding equity stakes in non-financial firms.
The empirical analysis indicates that bank shareholding is strongly and positively
correlated with the amount of long term debt granted to the firm by the bank. Moreover,
banks seem to hold equity mainly in companies that are relatively less profitable and
less dynamic, have more debt, have a large fraction of tangible assets and are less tightly
controlled. These results indicate that banks tend to hold shares of companies which are
current or prospective borrowers and that there is a complementarity between banks’
shareholding and lending. Evidence that banks have acquired equity to improve the
governance of firms, mitigating the asset substitution effect or agency costs, or to gather
an information advantage to allocate credit in an efficient way is very weak. Although
we cannot exclude the banks hold shares of non financial firms to participate to the
potential upside performance of the firm, the results are consistent with the hypothesis
that banks hold equities to influence the management of the company towards debt
repayment (sharehodler-debtholder conflict).
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we discuss the literature on banks’
equity investment focusing on the Japanese experience. In Section 3 we provide a de-
scription of the dataset. In Section 4 we present our empirical results on banks’ equity
investment. In Section 5 we analyze institutional investors’ shareholding.
2
Banks’ equity holdings of non financial companies: the-
ory and evidence
The literature on bank-firm relationships concentrates on the debt side and, in particu-
lar, on the effects of the so-called main bank relationship which arises when a bank acts
5
as a main lender to a firm and provides assistance on the governance and on the man-
agement of the company. A well established result shows that companies with a main
bank relationship are less liquidity-constrained (see, among others, [Hoshi et al., 1991,
Weinstein and Yafeh, 1998] for Japan and [Petersen and Rajan, 1994] for the US), but
the effect of a main bank-firm relationship on performance is mixed. [Weinstein and Yafeh, 1998]
show that firms with a main bank relationship in Japan are characterized by lower prof-
itability, lower growth rates and a higher cost of capital.
Also the evidence on the relationship between banks’ shareholding in non finan-
cial companies and their performance is mixed. In Japan, a nonlinear relationship
(decreasing and then increasing) between Tobin’s q and bank shareholding has been
detected by [Morck, et al., 2000]; [Yafeh and Yosha, 2003] show that ownership concen-
tration and debt reduce agency costs and managerial private benefits, but no effect is
associated with a main bank relationship; [Lichtenberg and Pushner, 1994] find a pos-
itive relationship between banks’ shareholding and increments of total productivity of
borrower firms. In Germany, [Gorton and Schmid, 2000] have shown that firm perfor-
mance benefits from concentrated ownership and in particular from bank shareholding;
[Chirinko and Elston, 2003], instead, obtain different results: bank control negatively
affects company profitability but statistical significance is weak or absent.
Our study differs from the ones quoted above in two major respects. First it tries to
ascertain whether also in the Italian financial system, which is quite different from both
the German and Japanese main bank systems, it is possible to detect a link between
bank shareholding and lending. In particular, it tries to establish whether, in the Italian
case, bank shareholding is a complement or rather a substitute of bank lending. Second,
we investigate whether available empirical evidence allows us to say something about the
motives behind the banks’ decisions to hold equity in non-financial firms.
On this last point it is important to be extremely careful, because inferring motives
from the data may be tricky. Banks hold equity mainly for three reasons: i) to partici-
pate to the potential upside performance of the company instead of receiving the more
conservative debt payoff; ii) to better monitor and condition the management of the firm,
6
reducing agency costs (management-shareholder conflict) and limiting the asset substi-
tution effect (shareholder-debtholder conflict); iii) to obtain information advantages in
the allocation of credit. In this last respect, bank shareholding may be viewed as a part
of relationship banking, see [Diamond, 1984].
According to these motivations, bank shareholding can be a substitute or a comple-
ment of lending: while the informational advantage argument leads to complementarity,
the first and the second motivation are ambiguous on this point: in the first case, the
choice between debt contract and equity depends on risk aversion and on the possibility
to hedge firm specific risk; in the second case it depends on the effectiveness of outside
blockholding and debt as monitors. If bank shareholding is driven by the desire to limit
the asset substitution effect, which arises when the existing assets of the firm are sub-
stituted with riskier assets to increase the likelihood of the potential upside in favor of
shareholders and against debtholders, then complementarity is expected.
The effects of bank shareholding on company performance are ambiguous: the second
and the third motivations may be associated with a positive performance because the
bank holding equities acts as a strong monitor to limit agency and asset substitution
costs but the effect becomes negative if the bank is also a creditor of the company and
simply aims to debt repayment in conflict with shareholders’ interests. Also the effect
of equity holding on bank lending is ambiguous: on one hand we have the classical
information advantage argument, on the other we have a change of incentive. The bank
wants to participate to potential upside and therefore is more reluctant to provision for
non performing loans, to terminate non profitable investments and to reduce loans to
troubled companies, i.e., we have the soft budget hypothesis
7
.
We can conclude that the second and the third motive can easily generate a cost rather
than a benefit both for the bank and the non financial company. Moreover the three
motives are not mutually exclusive and conclusive on complementarity/substitutability
between shareholding and lending.
Particularly relevant, for the purpose of this paper, is the literature on bank-firm cross
7
For a theoretical foundation of this hypothesis see [Dewatripont and Tirole, 1994, Berlin et al., 1996].
7
shareholding in Japan, see [Prowse, 1992, Flath, 1993, Sheard, 1994, Miyajima et al., 2003,
Miyajima and Kuroki, 2006, Franks et al., 2007].
8
Interestingly, the evaluation of the
main bank-firm relation and of cross shareholding in Japan has changed over time, and
is strictly correlated with the performance of the economy. [Prowse, 1992, Flath, 1993]
analyze bank shareholding in the 1980s. In the first paper, where a relationship be-
tween large equity stakes by banks and a high level of risk (represented by the return
standard error) is detected, the author claims that ”financial institutions’ equity invest-
ments are sensitive to benefits that can be obtained from exerting control over unstable
firms”. The evidence provided in the paper to support this view, however, is quite lim-
ited. [Flath, 1993] analyzes bank shareholding of non financial companies controlling for
debt endogeneity and obtains two interesting results: a) weak collateral, growth options
and high R&D expenses lead to more shareholding by the main bank and less leverage,
suggesting that agency/asymmetric information problems inhibit borrowing and induce
banks to detain shares; b) greater overall borrowing and borrowing from the main bank
elicit greater shareholding by the main bank and vice versa.
According to these results there is complementarity between lending and sharehold-
ing by the main bank, although the two phenomena represent a different response to
agency/asymmetric information problems. Moreover, the assessment of bank holding
equity in non financial firms is positive
9
.
8
[Chirinko and Elston, 2003] analyze bank shareholding in Germany, they show that bank share-
holding is a substitute for control: the likelihood of observing bank control is decreasing in ownership
concentration, the dividend yield and the cash flow over interest expenses ratio.
9
These results have been confirmed only in part by the analysis of bank blockbuilding after the second
world war. [Miyajima et al., 2003] analyzing the 1964-1969 period have shown that the change in bank
equity holdings in non financial companies was positively sensitive not only to lending relationships but
also to firm performance (return on assets, interest coverage ratio), growth opportunities and financial
conditions. [Franks et al., 2007] suggest that insiders’ shareholding increases in the post war period
are due to less effective creditor protection; analyzing incumbent shareholding (banks and other firms)
changes in the 1950-1955 and 1962-1967 periods, they provide evidence confirming this claim: high
leverage/financial distress cause an increase in bank shareholding through debt-equity swap; the relation
with financial health and performance, instead, is rather weak.
8
The cross shareholding system remained stable for a long time but things appear to
have changed considerably, coinciding with the deep economic and financial crisis that
hit Japan during the 1990s. With the increase in foreign shareholding, cross sharehold-
ing between banks and non financial firms began to dissolve: the fraction of shares ex-
changed in the stock market owned by banks went from 15.7% in 1990 to 7.7% in 2002, see
[Miyajima and Kuroki, 2006]. Analyzing the phenomenon, [Miyajima and Kuroki, 2006]
show that the likelihood of unwinding is small if there is a main banking relation-
ship and cross-shareholding.
The decision to sell shares by banks, instead, turned
out to be positively related with growth options and expected rates of return (shares
that are easy to sell) and only weakly negatively affected by credit risk. This be-
havior lead to a deterioration of banks’ portfolios. Confirming [Kang and Stulz, 2000,
Weinstein and Yafeh, 1998], these authors also show that bank ownership and main bank
relationships have had a negative effect on firm performance during the 1980s and 1990s.
This evaluation is supported by the evidence on banks’ lending behavior during the
Japanese financial and economic crisis in the 1990s. [Peek and Rosengren, 2005] show
that during the 1990s domestic bank loans in Japan continued to increase until the mid-
1990s: instead of reducing (increasing) loans to troubled (safe) firms, banks have mainly
increased loans to troubled borrowers (banks’ forbearance). Credit was not allocated in
a proper way, and this phenomenon was mainly concentrated on companies with strong
corporate affiliations, i.e. on firms belonging to a keiretsu, and when the bank belonged
to the same keiretsu of the company. We can conclude that bank-firm liaisons have
contributed to a bad allocation of credit and delayed the restructuring process of non
financial companies. An explicit statistically significant relation between bank holding
shares of non financial companies, non performing loans and loan loss provisions has
been detected by [Dewenter et al., 2007]
10
.
This evidence casts serious doubts on the rationale behind banks’ shareholding in
non financial companies and on its effects on firm management and credit allocation. In
10
A similar result has been obtained at the international level for relationship banks opposed to trans-
actional banks, see [Dewenter et al., 2006].
9
the case of Japan, empirical evidence has detected a strong complementarity between
lending and equity holding and that the informational/governance advantages tradition-
ally associated with banks’ equity holding have turned out to be instead a cost both for
banks and non financial companies.
3
Data and variable definitions
We analyze a dataset collected by Ricerche & Studi of Mediobanca on the largest finan-
cial and non financial Italian companies, including holding companies with consolidated
balance sheets. We restrict our attention to non financial companies. We consider seven
years of data (1994-2000). The sample varies over time, on average it includes 190 large
companies (82 companies are listed in the Italian stock exchange); on the whole we have
1450 observations. The dataset includes balance-sheet data, ownership structure data
as well as information on bank-firm debt relations. Since only a part of the companies is
listed in the Italian stock market, we cannot use information on market valuation. The
dataset is free of survivorship bias: a company belongs to the dataset depending on its
size, in case of a company exiting the dataset at some date previous observations are
included in the dataset.
To evaluate the rationale for bank shareholding and its degree of complementar-
ity/substitutability with leverage, we consider variables addressing specific aspects of
the company.
The most interesting aspect of our data-set is that we have information on bank-firm
debt relationships, and this allows us to get a clear picture on bank specific shareholding-
lending behavior. In the first part of our empirical work we consider a dummy variable
indicating whether a shareholding bank is also a lender to the firm (partloan), in the
second part we consider directly the percentage of the of debt that a firm has with a
shareholding bank (loanshare). Obviously a positive relationship between sharehodling
and either partloan or loanshare indicates complementarity with lending.
Although extremely indicative of the connection between shareholding and lending,
however, these variables are mute on the rationale of the connection. In order to obtain
10
some insights on this important issue, we include in the regressions a series of controls
that could be indicative of the motivations behind banks decisions to hold equity in non
financial firms.
The first control we use is company size, which is measured through the logarithm
of total assets (lasset), the number of employees (employees) and total sales (sales). It
is difficult to assess the relationship between size and bank shareholding. If the bank
acts as a monitor of the company or holds stocks to gather more information, then bank
shareholding is more likely in small firms.
A second, important control variable is firm performance. In general, the relationship
between bank shareholding and firm performance is ambiguous. High profitability is a
good signal for future returns but a bank can also be involved in a debt restructuring
processes (debt for equity swap) and in deals aiming at turning around poor performers.
Moreover, we expect equityholding to be negatively correlated with performance if the
bank acquires equity to protect its own interests as creditor or to monitor the company:
the less profitable is the company, in fact, the lower is the probability of debt repayment.
As indicators of profitability we consider the return on equity (roe) or the return on
assets (roa). Similar arguments hold for indicators of firm’s growth. We consider the
growth in the number of employees (growthempl ) and in the level of sales (growthsales)
with respect to the previous year. As the sample includes unlisted companies, we cannot
employ forward indicators of growth opportunities such as the market value over book
value (mvbv ) or the Tobin’s q (tobinq).
Further results on the relationship between bank shareholding and lending can be
obtained by considering the total debt/total assets ratio (leverage) and financial condi-
tions through the ratio of current earnings to the cost of debt (ebitda/debtcost). If bank
shareholding is positively related to leverage and negatively to ebitda/debtcost, then the
evidence is in favor of complementarity with lending rather than substitution. The ratio-
nale can be traced back to a governance motivation (banks hold shares to limit the asset
substitution in the interests of shareholders and to act as an effective monitor) or to a
negative motivation for the shareholders of the company (banks induce the company to
11
undertake more conservative policies directed toward debt repayment). It is difficult to
disentangle these two motivations.
To assess the relevance of the debtholder-shareholder conflict, we use the ratio be-
tween tangible assets and total assets (tangible/assets). Firms with fewer tangible assets
are likely to be more opaque, to be characterized by higher asset substitution costs and
higher bankruptcy costs in the event of financial distress and the shareholder/debtholder
conflict is more intense. Tangible assets can be used as collateral and therefore are as-
sociated with a higher leverage ratio. As a consequence a positive relation between the
fraction of tangible assets and bank shareholding provides evidence of complementarity
with lending and that the debtholder-shareholder conflict is not intense.
As it is widely documented, in the Italian financial market ownership of companies is
highly concentrated, see [Bianchi et al. (2001)]. In Table 1 we provide data on ownership
structure of companies listed in the Italian stock market. Note that the stake of the
largest shareholder is decreasing over time and the fraction of listed companies controlled
de jure (the largest shareholder holds a stake above 50%) has decreased significantly by
15%. However, ownership concentration is still high compared to other financial markets
and it is also interesting to note that banks’ and institutional investors’ shareholding is
quite limited.
To take into account these peculiarities of the Italian financial market, in our analysis
we consider ownership structure through the fraction of stocks of the largest shareholder
(lrgshr ) which is defined as the percentage of voting rights held by the largest share-
holder, or by the coalition of shareholders controlling the company. Notice that a bank
cannot be the largest/controlling shareholder of a non financial company and therefore
lrgshr does not include bank shareholding. In some regressions we consider the dummy
variable control assuming a value equal to 1 if the company is controlled (the largest
shareholder/coaltion holds a stake above 30%) and zero otherwise.
The variables lrgshr and control give us a measure of the degree of control exercised
by the largest shareholder over the firm, which is likely to influence the decision of a bank
to hold a stake. If the intention is to influence the management of the firm to favor the
12
Table 1: Ownership structure of listed companies
year
lrgshr outsid ins
bank
found inves
cont
contf
coalit
noncon
1996
50.4
10.7
1.9
4.3
3.8
0.8
66.8
12.2
4.8
16.2
1997
38.7
8.4
2.2
5.1
3.1
0.1
48.1
12.4
6.3
33.2
1998
33.8
9.7
2.5
4.8
5.2
0.1
32.3
21.7
7.4
38.6
1999
44.2
8.2
1.5
5.3
4.5
0.2
55
16.7
10.8
17.5
2000
44
9.4
3.2
5.9
5.0
0.3
51.4
18.5
9.6
20.5
Note: Data, from statistics by the Stock Exchange Authority (Consob), concern all the stock market
(including financial companies) and refer to stakes of shareholders holding stakes above 2% weighted by
the stock market capitalization. Columns 2-3 report the stake of shareholders controlling the company
(lrgshr ) and of non controlling relevant shareholders (outsid ), columns 4-7 report the stake detained by
insurance companies (ins), banks (bank ), foundations (found ), mutual/private equity funds (inves); the
last four columns report the fraction of companies controlled by absolute majority (cont), controlled de
facto
, i.e., the largest shareholder controls the company with a stake below 50% (contf ), controlled by a
coalition of shareholders (coalit), non controlled companies (noncon).
creditor, then tightly controlled firms are not very attractive and therefore the incentive
to acquire equity in this type of firms is smaller. On the other hand, with concentrated
ownership, private benefits of control (including exploitation of debtholders) are high,
and therefore banks have an incentive to hold shares and to monitor the company.
11
As a measure of investment liquidity we consider a dummy variable assuming value
equal to 1 if the company is listed and zero otherwise (listed ). If a bank holds equity
in order to condition management and solve governance problems, it will more likely
prefer unlisted firms, as these problems are likely to be more relevant in firms less open
to market scrutiny. The shareholder/debtholder conflict, instead, does not have a clear
relationship with the variable listed. On one side, in fact, the conflict is greater if a firm
is unlisted. On the other side, in case of distress, swapping debt with equity is easier if a
11
Ownership structure variables could be used, as in [Chirinko and Elston, 2003], to test for bank
stockholdings as a means of control substitution: obviously a large stake by the largest shareholder
is likely to be associated with a small stake by minority shareholders (including banks) but a negative
dependence of bank stockholdings on lrgshr or control also provides an indicator of the attempt by banks
to stabilize the control of the company.
13
firm is listed. Obviously, if the bank holds equity as a pure investment, listed companies
are likely to be more appealing.
We finally consider, as a further proxy for bank-firm relationships, the number of
bank-lending relationships which is measured as the number of banks currently lending
to the firm (banknr ). As for the variable partloan described above, a negative relationship
between bank shareholding and banknr is indicative of complementarity between bank
shareholding and lending. If main bank relationships occur, in fact, it is more likely that
equity holding and bank debt are closely tied.
Summary statistics of all the variables described above are reported in Table 2.
Companies of the sample on average have 11,522 employees and more than 2 billion
euros in sales. Profitability, as measured by the return on equity (roe), has not been
on average very high, just 6.25% during the sample period. Total debt over total assets
(leverage) amounted to about 0.6, a large fraction of the assets is actually tangible assets
(79%).
From the data we notice two peculiarities of the Italian corporate structure. Con-
firming data on listed companies reported above, ownership is strongly concentrated,
i.e., the average stake of the largest shareholder is next to 80%, and the median is 94%
while the stake held by banks (bankshr ) and institutional investors (instshr ) on average
is less than 2%. If we consider however only the companies where banks have a positive
equity stake we see that bank shareholding is 8.7% while average shareholding by the
controlling shareholder in these companies is 48.3%. The stake detained by the largest
shareholder and by banks do not sum up to 100%, as a matter of fact there are other
outside blockholders (institutional investors, companies, etc.). Note that even a stake
below 10% is enough to play a relevant role on the governance and company decisions:
the threshold to appoint members of the board of auditors of listed companies is usually
smaller than 3% and thresholds for shareholders’ activism (e.g. to promote a derivative
suit against executive directors) are below 5%. Confirming the evidence provided in
[Detragiache et al., 2000] and in many other papers, Italian firms have multiple banking
relationships: on average, companies of the sample have obtained long term loans by
14
5.42 banks and half of the firms of the sample have more than 4 banking relationships.
Table 2: Descriptive statistics on the full sample
Variable
mean
median
st. dev.
roe
6.25
8.17
50.86
roa
0.038
0.027
0.067
sales
2,333,718
852,153
5,291,202
employees
11,522
3,875
5,776,154
growthempl
0.07
-0.006
0.69
growthsales
0.29
0.07
3.33
ebitda/debtcost
1.133
0.328
10.489
leverage
0.6
0.64
0.256
tangible/assets
0.79
0.63
0.87
lrgshr
78.2
94.4
26.68
banknr
5.42
4.00
4.62
bankshr
1.53
0
5.49
instshr
1.36
0
5.86
mvbv#
1.97
1.18
6.92
tobinq#
1.27
1.05
0.77
Note: # computation has been restricted to the subsample of listed companies (483 observations).
4
Empirical analysis
We develop our analysis in three steps. First, we compare the sample of companies with
banks among their shareholders and the sample of companies with no bank shareholding.
Then we provide an analysis of the determinants of bank stockholdings through a Tobit
analysis. Finally, we single out a set of banks and we perform a Tobit regression on
the determinants of their stockholdings looking at bank-non financial company debt
relationships.
15
Table 3: Mean and median comparison of companies with banks’ shareholding (bank)
and companies without banks’ shareholding (no bank).
Mean
Median
no bank
bank
p-value
no bank
bank
p-value
roe
7.01
-11.1
0.003
8.85
5.23
0.001
roa
0.04
0.015
0.006
0.03
0.016
0.001
assets
920,713
1,450,537
0.023
242,455
415,881
0.001
sales
1,945,937
4,123,731
0.001
774,236
1,409,153
0.001
employees
9,509
20,809
0.001
3,535
7,920
0.001
growthempl
0.08
0.04
0.44
-0.005
-.010
0.1243
growthsales
18.16
31.66
0.085
6.54
6.9
0.639
ebitda/debtcost
1.118
1.205
0.91
0.344
0.276
0.003
leverage
0.584
0.656
0.001
0.638
0.68
0.001
tangible/assets
0.77
0.87
0.12
0.61
0.71
0.03
lrgshr
84.6
48.9
0.000
100
50.9
0.000
banknr
5.16
6.48
0.001
4
5
0.005
mvbv#
2.151
1.587
0.072
1.212
1.100
0.005
tobinq#
1.337
1.185
0.002
1.071
1.021
0.002
Note: p-value refers to the probability that mean or the median of the two samples are different. #
computation has been restricted to the subsample of listed companies (483 observations).
16
4.1
Univariate analysis
The univariate comparison of companies with bank shareholding and no bank share-
holding offers some interesting insights. The results of this comparison, with simple
univariate tests on the distribution of the variables (mean and median), are reported
in Table 3. In the column no bank we refer to the sample of companies with no bank
shareholding, while in the column bank we refer to companies with bank shareholding.
Companies with bank shareholding are less profitable - with a negative mean roe- rela-
tive to companies with no banks among shareholders. They are also characterized by a
larger size, as expressed by the level of sales, the number of employees and total assets.
While variables assessing past growth provide conflicting evidence with weak statistical
significance, forward looking growth indicators (computed on the subsample of listed
companies), such as tobinq (market value of assets over the book value) and mvbv (mar-
ket value over the book value), signal that bank shareholding is more likely in companies
with poor growth opportunities. We observe that companies with bank shareholding, on
average, have a higher leverage ratio and a higher fraction of tangible assets, control is
less concentrated and the number of bank relationships is higher.
4.2
Tobit analysis
A large number of firms in our sample does not have banks among their shareholders. Our
dependent variable, the fraction of a firm’s equity owned by banks (bankshr), is therefore
only partly continuous with positive probability mass at zero. The estimation method
that is most commonly used, in this case, is the Tobit model. In Table 4 we provide a
Tobit analysis of our panel. Building on the discussion about the motives behind banks’
decision to hold equity in a firm and on the univariate analysis provided above, we
first analyze a reference model where we include, as regressors, lasset, ebitda/debtcost,
leverage, tangible/assets, listed, control, partloan, roe, growthempl (see column 1). In
the second column, we use an alternative indicator of firm growth (growthsales) and in
the last two columns we include banknr as exogenous variable, restricting our attention
to a subsample.
17
We choose to use, for these regressions, a random effect estimator rather than a
pooled estimator. The use of a pooled estimator, in fact, is not indicated when the
proportion of the total variance contributed by the panel-level variance component (the
Rho in the last two rows of the table) is different from zero, which is actually the case
in our estimates. We have excluded the fixed effects estimator because of the large
reduction in the number of observations that this would imply
12
. For each regression
we compute the maximum value of the likelihood function L(Ω). The chi2 statistic is
χ
2
= 2 {ln L(Ω) − ln L(ω)} where L(ω) is the value of the likelihood function under the
assumption that all coefficients except for the constant are zero. As we can see from our
estimates, all the regressions pass the chi2 test.
A first, very important result of the analysis is that the dummy variable partloan,
that takes the value of 1 if the bank that acquires a stake in the capital of the firm is also
a creditor of the firm and 0 otherwise, not only is positive, but it also turns out to be the
one with the highest degree of statistical significance. There is therefore, a very strong
and significant complementarity between bank shareholding and lending: if a bank is a
lender to the firm, then is also more likely to hold equity.
Beside the variable partloan, there are only two variables that are highly significant
in all the regressions: the roe which enters with a negative coefficient, and the ratio of
debt to total assets (leverage) with a positive coefficient. Given the particular meaning of
our dependent variable, this implies that banks not only tend to acquire equity in firms
that are unprofitable and highly indebted, but also the size of their stake is negatively
correlated with profitability and positively correlated with leverage.
Consistently with this interpretation, the indicator of debt sustainability (ebitda/debtcost)
is negatively correlated with our dependent variable, although not always statistically
significant. As far as growth perspectives are concerned, the variable growthempl is never
statistically significant, but the coefficient of the alternative growth indicator (growth-
sales) is negative and significant in equation (2) although not in equation (4).
12
In a fixed effects estimation observations non associated with a change in the fixed effects are dropped
from the regression. Since in our sample banks’ shareholding, for each firm, does not change very much
across time the use of fixed effects would imply a large drop in the number of observations.
18
Table 4: Bank shareholding
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
lasset
0.76620
0.74310
0.22116
0.23132
(5.21)***
(5.03)***
(0.97)
(1.02)
ebitda/debtcost
-0.0001
-0.0001
-0.0001
0.0001
(1.66)*
(1.60)
(0.06)
(0.01)
leverage
4.19786
4.17689
5.09793
5.28276
(5.94)***
(5.99)***
(4.00)***
(4.25)***
tangibile/asset
0.330
0.288
1.515
1.495
(1.42)
(1.22)
(2.80)***
(2.88)***
listed
0.39664
0.33008
0.41503
0.41082
(1.90)*
(1.64)
(0.88)
(0.87)
control
-0.03047
0.00428
-3.23617
-3.33425
(0.08)
(0.01)
(4.40)***
(4.74)***
partloan
8.61651
8.06547
8.29176
8.40252
(17.50)*** (16.88)*** (12.88)*** (13.36)***
roe
-0.00595
-0.00553
-0.00933
-0.00925
(4.64)***
(4.42)***
(5.67)***
(5.77)***
growthempl
-0.00813
-0.00638
0.14003
(0.05)
(0.44)
growthsales
-0.00068
0.00042
(2.46)**
(0.17)
banknr
-0.07090
-0.07233
(1.65)*
(1.72)*
constant
0.76853
0.77768
0.49039
0.492191
(0.014)
(0.0137)
(0.0466)
(0.0439)
Observations
1160
1155
797
787
Nr. of sector
206
205
171
170
Log likelihood
-3126.1
-3089.8
-2166.7
-2141.5
Wald chi2(8)
1300.4
1237.0
347.7
384.1
p.value
0.0001
0.0001
0.0001
0.0001
Rho
0.7683
0.7776
0.4904
0.4922
St. error
0.0141
0.0137
0.0466
0.0439
Note: Tobit analysis, the endogenous variable is the stake of the company held by banks. Absolute value
of z statistics is reported in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
19
The coefficient of the dummy variable control, indicating whether the company is
controlled by the main shareholders, is negative and significant in two out of four regres-
sions and insignificant in the others, indicating a preference for the acquisition of equity
in less controlled firms where the bank may exert greater influence
13
. The coefficient of
the variable listed is always positive with an acceptable level of significance in the first
regression. The variable tangible/assets, enters all the regressions with a positive sign
and in the last two regressions is statistically significant.
In the Tobit regressions the number of banks that have credit relationships with the
firm (banknr ) is negatively correlated with the equity stake held by banks and significant
at the 10% level, which shows that banks tend to acquire equity when the company
borrows from a small number of banks.
Overall, it seems that Italian banks tend to become shareholders of the companies
they lend to, and this indicates quite clearly that shareholding and lending complement
each other. Banks seem to hold equity in companies that are highly leveraged, that do not
generate enough earnings relatively to their financial obligations and are neither the most
profitable nor the most dynamic. We cannot exclude that high leverage and bank equity
are jointly driven by a poor performance. Moreover, banks are shareholders of firms
that are less tightly controlled and that have a smaller number of credit relationships,
i.e. where it is easy to exercise some form of influence.
This evidence can be interpreted according to the hypotheses introduced in Section
2 on the rationale for bank shareholding. Results are not too informative on the first
hypothesis: weak profitability/financial conditions can be associated with turn around
deals and so are not at odds with the pure investment motive. We can exclude that
banks detain stocks to gather an informational advantage to allocate credit in a proper
way, as a matter of fact there is no evidence that banks hold equities in more opaque
companies. The second (governance) hypothesis deserves a deeper analysis.
Results indicate that banks tend to hold equity in order to influence the management
13
The result is partially due to the fact that the stake of outside blockholders in a controlled company
is smaller than in a non controlled company
20
of the company. However, this behavior does not seem to be dictated by some kind of
”virtuous” motivation, i.e., to solve agency problems, to reduce asset substitution or
to accompany the firm in a solid growth path. Rather, the fact that banks tend to be
shareholders of firms that have a lower return on equity and a large, unsustainable debt
seems to indicate that they intend to use their influence as shareholders to induce the
management to undertake actions which are favorable to creditors. This is even more
likely if bank shareholding is the result of a debt-equity swap undertaken as a means
to restructure debt. If the firm is under financial distress, in fact, the shareholder-
debtholder conflict becomes particularly acute. The only finding that is not supportive
of this interpretation is that in the last two regressions bank shareholding is positively
and significantly related to the share of tangible assets. Since this finding is limited to a
subsample of firms we cannot draw definitive conclusions on the issue. It might indicate,
however, that the shareholder-debtholder conflict is not very intense.
One problem with the estimates presented above is the possibility that the variable
partloan is not entirely exogenous, i.e. that a bank’s decision to lend to a firm is influenced
by the bank holding an equity stake in the borrowing firm. We think that this possibility
is quite remote, especially considering that partloan is a dichotomous variable, i.e. does
not refer to the size of the loan but to the choice of lending or not lending to the
firm.
A profit mazimizing bank whose main business is to grant credit will lend to
any firm independently of whether it holds equity of some specific firms and actually,
considering that banks, in our sample, seem to hold equity in the ”weakest” companies,
it is quite unlikely that the decision to grant credit is influenced by banks’ shareholding.
Nevertheless this possibility cannot be excluded a priori and therefore, in order to assess
whether partloan is indeed endogenous we have performed the Smith-Blundell exogeneity
test for Tobit regressions
14
.
14
For details on this test see [Smith and Blundell, 1986]. The test assumes that, under the null hy-
pothesis, the model is appropriately specified with all explanatory variables as exogenous; under the
alternative hypothesis, the suspected endogenous variable (in our case partloan) is expressed as a linear
projection of a set of instruments, and the residuals from this first-stage regression are added to the
model. Under the null hypothesis, these residuals should have no explanatory power.
21
To perform the test we run a set of pooled Tobit regressions where the variable
partloan has been instrumented by exogenous variables (the dummy variable bond, which
takes the value 1 if the firm finances itself also through the issue of bonds and zero
otherwise, the dummy variable ministry, which takes the value 1 if if the firm is indebted
with the Ministry of the Industry and 0 otherwise). These last two variables play an
important role in the firms’ decision to borrow from a bank since they imply the recourse
to non bank funds, but they are clearly not relevant for a bank’s decision to hold a share
of the capital of a non financial firm. In all the various specifications of the model
considered above we could never reject the null hypothesis that the variable partloan is
exogenous.
15
The regressions in Table 4, therefore, do not suffer from the inconsistency
that would be induced if indeed partloan turned out to be endogenous.
4.3
Bank specific equity holding
In the previous section we have shown that bank shareholding of non financial firms
is explained, among others, by the fact that the firm is also a borrower of one of the
shareholding banks. The finding suggests that there is a relationship between a bank’s
equity stake in a non financial firm and the fact that the company is also indebted to the
shareholding bank. If we want to investigate, at a deeper level, the positive relationship
between firm indebtedness and bank shareholding, we must try to investigate whether
there exists a direct relationship between the fraction of shares owned by a bank in one
particular non financial firm and the amount of long term loans this bank has granted
to the same firm. In order to do this, we construct a dataset where we consider the
15
Consider for example the basic specification of the model, i.e the one corresponding to column (1)
of Table 4. If the variable ministry is employed as an instrument of partloan, together with all the other
covariates, the test statistic F(1,846)= 0.0001763 with P-value = 0.9894. If the variable bond is employed
as an instrument of partloan, together with all the other exogenous variables, the test statistic F(1,939)
= 0.1518892 with P-value = 0.6968. If both the variables ministry and bond are employed as instruments
of partloan, together with all the other exogenous variables, the test statistic F(1,755) = 1.133895 with
P-value = 0.2873. Similar values are obtained using different specifications of the model, as in columns
(2) and (3) of Table 4.
22
seven most important banks (Banca Intesa, Unicredit, Capitalia, MPS, BNL, Sanpaolo
and Mediobanca) that appear in the Mediobanca survey and we consider, as dependent
variable, the equity stake held by bank i into firm j at time t. We call this variable
bankown. As in the previous analysis, we use a panel Tobit analysis with random effects.
The dependent variable is regressed on the variable loanshare, which is defined as the
amount of long term debt firm j owes to bank i at time t, as a percentage of total long
term debt of firm j, and other firm specific variables. Among the other covariates we
include total assets (asset), total sales (sales) and the variables we have used in the
previous regressions (growthempl, growthsales, ebitda/debtcost, leverage, tangible/assets
and listed ). We include both the variables lrgshr and control to capture ownership
structure. In order to account for heterogeneity accross banks we include a dummy
variable that, for each bank i = 1..., 7, takes value 1 when bank i is involved and 0
otherwise. Coefficients for these variables are not reported below.
The results of our estimates are reported in Table 5. As we can see from all the
estimates reported in the Table, the variable loanshare, which indicates the percentage
of long term debt that a firm owes to a specific bank, not only has a positive sign, but is
also the most significant determinant of the equity stake of the bank in that firm. Banks’
decision to hold capital of a non financial firm is strongly influenced, therefore, by the
amount of credit granted to the firm, confirming the strong complementarity between
bank shareholding and lending that we have found in the previous section. The sign of
the other covariates, again, seems to indicate the existence of a shareholder-debtholder
conflict: the coefficient of roe is always negative, and highly significant in two cases
out of three, the growth variable growthempl is insignificant and has a negative sign,
although the other growth variable (growthsales) in the last equation has a positive
and statistically significant coefficient, the variable leverage has always a positive sign
(although it looses significance in equations 2 and 3) indicating that banks tend to acquire
equity of indebted firms. The signs of the variables listed, lrgshr and control show that
banks tend to hold equity of firms which are more transparent and less tightly controlled.
23
Table 5: Bank specific regressions
(1)
(2)
(3)
loanshare
0.2760
0.07782
0.29393
(5.58)***
(3.23)***
(5.9)***
roe
-0.0002
-0.00008
-0.00017
(2.30)**
(2.01)**
(1.28)
asset
0.0005
0.00053
(2.56)**
(2.67)***
sales
0.00001
(2.02)**
growthempl
-0.0033
-0.00386
(0.27)
(0.73)
growthsales
0.00006
(2.16)**
ebitda/debcost
-0.0001
-0.00001
-0.00001
(0.10)
(0.46)
(0.13)
leverage
0.0913
0.01495
0.07266
(2.14)**
(0.68)
(1.66)*
tangible/assets
-0.0197
-0.01025
-0.01393
(1.02)
(1.48)
(0.54)
listed
0.3055
0.05421
0.24263
(1675)***
(3.84)***
(5.00)***
control
-0.0875
-0.05270
(1.79)*
(2.20)**
lrgshr
-0.00211
(3.11)***
Constant
-0.0080
0.06288
0.02731
(0.14)
(2.10)**
(0.32)
Observations
8261
8883
8262
Number of sector
206
206
206
Log likelihood
-9301.1
-9383.4
-9094.8
Wald chi2(8)
444.7
79.2
323.3
p.value
0.0001
0.0001
0.0001
Note: Tobit regressions, the endogenous variable is the stake held by a specific bank. Absolute value of
z statistics is reported in parentheses.* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
24
5
Institutional investors
Since results described in Table 4 suggest that banks, in deciding to hold shares of non
financial firms, do not act as normal investors focusing on profitability and financial
solidity, an interesting question is whether banks differ, in this respect, from other in-
stitutional investors. In order to address this issue, we analyze whether institutional
investors’ shareholding is related to the explanatory variables included in the previous
model. We include, among institutional investors, insurance companies, mutual and
pension funds and we explicitly exclude banks. In Table 6, we report the results of
Tobit regressions with random effects, where the dependent variable is the equity stake
of institutional investor (excluding banks) in a particular firm. Note that institutional
investors on average hold a stake equal to 1.36% (banks hold a stake equal to 1.53%).
Equations estimated in Table 6 include essentially the same explanatory variables
as the reference model of Table 4.
16
Notice that, differently from what happens in the
previous analysis on banks’ shareholding, the coefficient of roe is positive although not
statistically significant, and the coefficient of leverage is negative and non significant.
The two major determinants of institutional investors’ shareholding seem to be the size
indicator lsales and the variable listed. To a lesser extent, also the variable lrgshr, which
is the share of the larger shareholder of the company, is positive and significant.
These results suggest the existence of a significant difference between the motiva-
tions behind institutional investors’ shareholding in non-financial firms and those of
banks. Unlike banks, that tend to hold equity in non performing, highly indebted firms,
institutional investors seem to prefer large firms that are listed in the stock market and
that are less tightly controlled. These results do not support the view that banks act as
pure investors aiming at maximizing investment returns and confirm the hypothesis that
bank shareholding has different motivations, i.e., the desire to influence the management
16
Obviously we have excluded the variables referring to the bank-firm lending relationships. Moreover
we have used as indicator of size, the logarithm of total sales, and as an indicator of firm growth the
logarithm of sales growth. We have observed, in fact, that the use of lasset and growthempl creates some
collinearity problems.
25
Table 6: Institutional investors’ shareholding (excluding banks)
(1)
(2)
lsales
0.2341
0.2864
(4.07)***
(4.57)***
ebitda/debtcost
0.0001
0.0001
(0.25)
(0.29)
leverage
-0.1801
-0.2243
(0.24)
(0.30)
tangible/asset
0.0632
0.0549
(0.17)
(0.15)
listed
1.2777
0.8894
(3.68)***
(2.14)**
control
-0.3818
(0.67)
lrgshr
-0.0113
(1.68)*
roe
0.0013
0.0014
(0.72)
(0.78)
growthsales
0.0005
0.0005
(1.18)
(1.23)
Observations
1156
1163
Number of sector
205
205
Log likelihood
-3507.0
-3522.8
Wald chi2(8)
243.7
277.3
p.value
0.0001
0.0001
Rho
0.6989
0.7034
Note: Tobit regression, the endogenous variable is the fraction of shares held by institutional investors.
Absolute value of z statistics is reported in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ***
significant at 1%.
26
of the company, or simply by debt-equity swaps.
6
Conclusions
We have analyzed, in this paper, the motivations behind banks’ shareholding of non
financial firms for a panel of large Italian firms in a period that followed immediately
the introduction, in the Italian system, of universal banking as the standard form of
organization of the banking system.
Italian banks tend to invest in firms that have a credit relationship with them, indicat-
ing the existence of a strong complementarity between bank shareholding and lending.
Moreover, unlike other institutional investors, bank hold equity of firms that are less
profitable, more indebted and less tightly controlled which seem to suggest that bank
shareholding is motivated by the need to solve, in their favor, the debtholder/shareholder
conflict, i.e., to induce companies to undertake actions that would maximize the prob-
ability of debt repayment. There is little support, in the data, for the existence of
a virtuous bank-non financial company shareholding relation associated with gover-
nance/monitoring arguments.
We can conclude that, after the deep financial deregulation process occurred in the
1990s, we have not observed a significant move of the Italian banking system toward
a more active involvement in the management of firms, to improve their governance or
to overcome informational asymmetries, i.e., the factors that were considered, especially
in the literature of the early 1990s, as the major advantage of the main bank systems
of Germany and Japan. The lack of an involvement of banks in the governance of non
financial firms is consistent with results obtained by the recent literature on the Japanese
experience and cast doubt on the positive role of banks as equity holders of non financial
companies.
27
References
[Banca d’Italia, 2006]
Banca d’Italia (2006) I conti finanziari: la storia, i metodi, l’Italia,
i confronti internazionali.
[Bartirolo and De Bonis, 2005]
Bartirolo L. and De Bonis R. (2005) The financial sys-
tems of European countries: theoretical issues and empirical evidence. Irving Fisher
Committee Bulletin, 21, July.
[Berlin et al., 1996]
Berlin, M., John, K. and Saunders, A. (1996) Bank equity stakes in
borrowing firms and financial distress. Review of Financial Studies, 9: 889-919.
[Bianchi et al. (2001)]
Bianchi M., Bianco M., Enriques L. (2001), Pyramidal groups
and the separation between ownership and control in Italy, in F. Barca e M. Becht
(eds.), The control of corporate Europe, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
[Bianco and Chiri, 1997]
Bianco, M., and Chiri, S. (1997) Le partecipazioni bancarie
nelle imprese in Italia: investimenti e ristrutturazioni finanziarie. Banca, Impresa e
Societ´
a, XVI: 393-423.
[Chirinko and Elston, 2003]
Chirinko, R. and Elston (2003) Finance, control, and prof-
itability: the influence of German banks. Forthcoming Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization.
[Cobham, Cosci and Mattesini, 1999]
Cobham, R., Cosci, S. and Mattesini, F. (1999)
The Italian Financial System: neither Bank Based nor Market Based. The Manchester
School, n.3 vol 67, June.
[Detragiache et al., 2000]
Detragiahce, E, Garella, P. and Guiso L. (2000) Multiple ver-
sus single banking relationships: theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 55: 1133-
1155.
[Dewatripont and Tirole, 1994]
Dewatripont, M. and Tirole, J. (1994) A theory of debt
and equity: diversity of securities and manager-shareholder congruence. Quarterly
Journal of Economics: 1027-1054.
28
[Dewenter et al., 2006]
Dewenter K., Hess, A. (2006) International evidence on relation-
ship and transactional banks as delgated monitors, mimeo.
[Dewenter et al., 2007]
Dewenter K., Hamao, Y. and Hess, A.(2007) Banks’ equity hold-
ings and the soft budget problem: evidence from Japan’s prolonged recession, mimeo.
[Diamond, 1984]
Diamond D. (1984), Financial intermediation and delegated monitor-
ing. Review of Economic Studies, 51, pp. 393-414.
[Flath, 1993]
Flath D. (1993) Shareholding in the Kieretsu, Japan’s Financial Groups.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 75: 249-257.
[Franks et al., 2007]
Franks J., Mayer C., Miyajima H. (2007) Evolution of ownership:
the curious case of Japan. mimeo.
[Gompers and Metrick, 2001]
Gompers, P. and Metrick, A. (2001) Institutional investors
and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics: 229-259.
[Gorton and Schmid, 2000]
Gorton, G. and Schmid, F. (2000) Universal banking and
the performance of German firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 58: 29-80.
[Hoshi et al., 1991]
Hoshi, T., Kashyap, A. and Scharfstein, D. (1991) Corporate struc-
ture, liquidity, and investment: Evidence from Japanese industrial groups. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 106: 33-60.
[Kang and Stulz, 2000]
Kang, J. and Stulz, R. (2000) Do banking shocks affect borrow-
ing firm performance? An analysis of the Japanese experience. Journal of Business,
73: 1-23.
[La Porta et al., 1998]
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., shleifer, A., Vishny R. (1998)
Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106: 1113-55.
[Lichtenberg and Pushner, 1994]
Lichtenberg, F. and Pushenr, G. (1994) Ownership
structure and corporate performance in Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 6:
239-261.
29
[Miyajima et al., 2003]
Miyajima H., Haramura K. and Enami Y. (2003) Evolution of
ownership strcuture in postwar Japan: formulation and unwinding of stable share-
holders. Financial Review 68.
[Miyajima and Kuroki, 2006]
Miyajima H. and Kuroki F. (2006) The unwinding of cross-
shareholding in Japan: causes, effects and implications. Mimeo.
[Morck, et al., 2000]
Morck, R., Nakamura, M. and Shivdasani, A. (2000) Banks, own-
ership structure, and firm value in Japan. Journal of Business, 73: 539-567.
[Peek and Rosengren, 2005]
Peek J., Rosengren E. (2005) Unnatural selection: perverse
icnentives and the misallocation of credit in Japan. The American Economic Review,
95: 1144-1166.
[Petersen and Rajan, 1994]
Petersen, M. and Rajan, R. (1994) The benefits of lending
relationships: evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance, XLIX: 3-37.
[Prowse, 1992]
Prowse S. (1992) The structure of corporate ownership in Japan. Journal
of Finance, 47: 1121-1140.
[Sheard, 1994]
Sheard, P. (1994) Interlocking shareholdings and corporate governance
in Japan, in M. Aoki and R. Dore eds. The Japanese firm: sources of competitive
strength. Oxford, Oxford University Press, 324-349.
[Smith and Blundell, 1986]
Smith, R.J. and Blundell, R.W. (1986) An exogeneity test
for a simultaneous equation Tobit model with an application to labor supply. Econo-
metrica, 54, 3: 679-685.
[Weinstein and Yafeh, 1998]
Weinstein, D. and Yafeh, Y. (1998) On the costs ofa bank-
centered financial system: evidence from the changing main bank relationships in
Japan. Journal of Finance, 53: 635-672.
[Yafeh and Yosha, 2003]
Yafeh, Y. and Yosha, O. (2003) Large shareholders and banks:
who monitors and how? Economic Journal, 113: 128-146.
30