Managerial
Managerial
Economics
Economics
Jarek Neneman
601305093
Auctions and competitive bidding
(ch. 17, Samuelson & Marks)
Auctions
Everything is worth what
it’s purchaser will pay for it
Auctions
A exercise to start with – bidding for a
jar of money.
Take the look at the jar
Write down:
- estimated value of the jar (i. e. money)
- sealed bid for the jar
The person with the highest bid will win and
pay and be given an equivalent of the money
in the jar
Auctions
Auctions and competitive bidding
Auctions were used by the ancient
Babylonians as a way of distributing wives.
The two most frequently used methods of
selecting a best alternative:
- sealed-bid auction
- English auction,
let’s play it!
- Third kind of auction method is Dutch
auction
Auctions
The advantages of auctions
Auctions are between:
- posted prices, and
- negotiations
Auctions ensure that competition among
buyers sets the highest price.
Auctions are less time-consuming than
negotiations.
Let’s see the example
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
A stock repurchase.
A company is considering buying-back some
of its stocks.
The current price is: $67 per share
Management believes the value of the stock
is: $80 per share
Management’s offer would be: $70, $72 or
$74
The response of shareholders is not known
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
Shareholders response (Q)
Price
strong medium weak
$
(π=1/3) (π=1/3) (π=1/3)
70
13
9
6
72
14
12
8
74
18
15
12
Company’s profit is:
($80-P)*Q
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
What buy back price should the firm set?
Shareholders response (Q)
Price
strong
medium
weak
$
(π=1/3)
(
π=1/3)
(π=1/3)
70
13
9
6
72
14
12
8
74
18
15
12
E(Π
$70
) = 1/3*10*13 + 1/3*10*9 + 1/3*10*6 =
93.3
E(Π
$72
) = 1/3*8*14 + 1/3*8*12 + 1/3*8*8 =
90.67
E(Π
$74
) = 1/3*6*13 + 1/3*6*9 + 1/3*6*6 = 90
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
Instead of setting the buy-back price, the firm
can organize an auction.
In this system, each shareholder tenders any
number of shares at a price he names. eg. „I
will sell 10 at $70 or 20 at $72”.
After collecting of the tenders, the firm buys
the shares at a single common price.
What is the advantage of this „auction?
Before deciding on price, the firm knows the
shareholders’ response.
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
The firm’s most profitable offer (price) is
contingent on demand.
Shareholders response (Q)
Price
strong
medium
weak
$
(π=1/3)
(
π=1/3)
(π=1/3)
70
13
9
6
72
14
12
8
74
18
15
12
Strong response: price: $70, profit: $130
Medium response: price: $72, profit: $96
Weak response: price: $74, profit: $72
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – a stock
repurchase
Strong demand: price: $70, profit: $130
Medium demand: price: $72, profit: $96
Weak demand: price: $74, profit: $72
E(Π)= 1/3*130 + 1/3*96 + 1/3*72 = $99.3
Auction compared to posted prices increased
expected profit by $6.
$6 is the expected value of perfect
information about response
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – bidding vs.
bargaining
Searching for best price revisited
Seller believes that the potential buyers’
offers to purchase the division are uniformly
distributed in the range form $40-64m
The average is $52m
Seller’s reservation price is: $40m
What will be the average price in negotiation
with single buyer?
$46m. on average is very likely (profit from
transaction is split fifty-fifty).
Auctions
The advantages of auctions – bidding vs.
bargaining
Searching for best price revisited
The firm may do better by selling with use of
sealed-bid auction.
With 6 buyers, the price offered by the
highest bidder will be $60m. on average.
The sources of higher price are twofold:
- the higher the number of bidders, the
higher the probability that the one will hold a
high value
- the higher the number of bidders, the
stronger the incentive for them to place bid
near to its true value.
Auctions
Bidder strategies
Optimal bid depends on:
- reservation price
- assessment of the extent of bidding
competition
- type of auction (the most important factor)
Auctions
Bidder strategies
Time for another auction
Vickery auction (second-price (second-
bid) auction)
The highest bid wins the item.
But the price is equal to the second-highest
bid
Auctions
Bidder strategies
Independent private value setting
Each bidder assesses an individual value
(reservation price) for the item up for bid.
Each bidder’s value is independent of the
other’s
Values are private and bidders are aware of
the common probability distribution.
The profit of the bidder is:
v
i
- P
Auctions
Bidder strategies – English and Dutch
auctions
English and Dutch auctions
In oral English auctions bids continually
increase until the last and highest bidder
wins.
Bidder’s strategy: bid up to the reservation
price if necessary – dominant strategy
P is close to the second-highest reservation
price: v
2nd
.
The seller can obtain exactly the same price
using Vickery auction (second-price (-
bid) auction)
P
2nd
= P
E
= v
2nd
Auctions
Bidder strategies – English and Dutch
auctions
In Dutch auction the auctioneer starts the
sale by calling out a high price and the
lowers the price until a bid is made.
Optimal strategy in Dutch auction is
significantly different than in English auction
In Dutch auction there is risk, that another
buyer bid and win the item
In English auction there is no risk
Dutch auctions are similar to sealed-bid
auctions – the price achieved by seller is the
same
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions
Sealed-bid auctions are used to sell unique
items
Each bidder faces trade-off between
probability and profitability of winning
What bid will maximize the bidder’s expected
profit?
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions
Strategy against a bid distribution
To win the auction the firm must beat the
best competiting bid.
The distribution of competing bid is a key to
success.
An example
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
v
1
= $342 thousand
E(Π) = (342 – b)*[probability (b wins)]
There are two more bidders
Assessment winning chances and expected
profit are given in the table
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
Bid
Winning Probability
Expected
$
profit
of winning
profit
300
42
0.00
0.00
310
32
0.06
1.92
320
22
0.25
5.50
326
16
0.42
6.67
328
14
0.49
6.86
332
10
0.64
6.40
336
6
0.81
4.86
340
2
1.00
2.00
Optimal bid is:
$328
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
Firm’s winning chance depends on probability
that the best competing bid (BCB) is
smaller than the firm’s own bid.
H curve is graphical presentation of BCB
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
1.0
.8
.6
.49
.4
.2
0
Probability
H curve
Probability
b = 328 wins
Firm 1's profit
v - b
310
300
320 328
342
Firm 1's
optimal bid
Firm 1’s
Reservation
price
At bid = $328, the area of the rectangle (342-b)H(b) is the
biggest.
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
1.0
.8
.6
.49
.4
.2
0
Probability
H curve
Probability
b = 328 wins
Firm 1's profit
v - b
310
300
320 328
342
Firm 1's
optimal bid
Firm 1’s
Reservation
price
H curve is graphical
presentation of
BCB
It precisely measures
the firm’s winning
chances for its
various bids
Median of the BCB is
slightly higher
than $328.
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
Arriving at BCB
Let G(b) denote the cumulative distribution
function for the bid of a single competitor.
If firm’s bid is b, then the chances that this
bid is higher than the bid of the single
competitor is G(b)
What if there are two competitors?
If bids are independent of one another, then
probability, that firm’s bid is better than both
competiting bids is:
[G(b)]
2
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
Generally:
H(b) = [G(b)]
n-1
for n-1 competitors firm is facing
An example continued
Firm’s assessment is that each competitor’s
bid will be in the range of $300 and $340,
with all values in between equally likely. This
implies:
G(B) = (b-300)/40
With two competitors: H(b) = [(b-300)/40]
2
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
N-1=
2
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
N-1=
2
, n-1=
3
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
N-1=
2
, n-1=
3
, n-1=
5
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
N-1=
2
, n-1=
3
, n-1=
5
, n-1=
10
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
an example
With increasing number of competitors, the
bid distribution of the typical firm, G(b), will
be shifted towards higher bids.
This happens because:
- there are more competitors (that could be
seen on the previous graphs)
- each of them raise its bid
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
Equilibrium bidding strategies
Usually it is difficult for a firm to assess G(b)
or H(b)
All competitors are setting competitive bid,
taking into account others’ strategies, i.e.
there is interdependence among bidding
strategies
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
Bidding for the good with common value.
All bidders have the same reservation price.
The unique equilibrium has each bidder
submitting a sealed bid exactly equal to this
common value (reservation price).
Analogy for Bertrand competition
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
Bidding for the good with different private
values
n bidders,
v
i
private value
b
i
sealed bid
Buyers’ values are drawn independently from
a common distribution
Buyers values are independent
Each buyer’s value is uniformly distributed
between $300 and $360
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
If bidder knows his v
i
but do not know the
reservation prices of the other competitors,
then
his equilibrium bidding strategy is:
b
i
= 0.5 * 300 + 0.5v
i
For v
i
= 300, b
i
=300
For v
i
= 360, b
i
= 330
Expected profit of the first firm is:
E(Π
1
) = (v
1
– b
1
)[probability(b
1
wins)]
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
If firm 2 uses equilibrium bidding strategy,
then its competiting bids are distributed
uniformly between $300 and $330,
Thus b
1
wins with probability:
(b
1
– 300)/30, plugging this into expected
profit function gives:
E(Π
1
) = (v
1
– b
1
)*[(b
1
– 300)/30]
Setting dE(Π
1
)/db
1
= (v
1
– 2b
1
+300)/30 to
zero, implies:
b
1
= 0.5 * 300 + 0.5v
1
Auctions
Bidder strategies – sealed-bid auctions –
interdependence
For n competiting firms, the common
equilibrium strategy is:
b
i
= (1/n)*L + [(n-1)/n]* v
i
In sealed-bid auction, the equilibrium
strategy is to submit a bid b
i
, equal to the
expected value of the highest of the n-1
other buyers values, conditional on these
values being lower than v
i
.
b
i
= E(v’|v’≤v
i
)
Auctions
Bidder strategies – common values and the
Winner’s curse
Auctions for common but unknown value
Bids (B)
Estimates (E)
B
V
Bid distribution is centered to the left, as
bidders are seeking profits and bid below
the estimate of value
Auctions
Bidder strategies – common values and the
Winner’s curse
Winner’s curse – after the auction (ex post)
winner finds that the good is worth less than
the price paid for it.
Overestimation of the value is the source of
winner’s curse
Winning conveys information about the
bidder’s estimate relative to others.
Winner’s curse depends on:
degree of uncertainty
number of bidders
Auctions
Bidder strategies – common values and the
Winner’s curse
There is a significant difference between
sealed-bid auction and English auction of an
common, but unknown value item.
Observing the number of active bidders and
when they drop out conveys information
about competitor’s estimates of the item’s
value.
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Optimal auctions from the seller’s perspective
Expected auction revenue
In private value model and risk-neutral buyer,
English, sealed-bid, Dutch and Vickrey
auctions generate identical expected
revenues – revenue equivalence theorem
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Optimal auctions from the seller’s perspective
Seller’s expected revenue in the English and
Vickrey auctions:
E(P
E
) = E(v
2nd
)
Seller’s expected revenue in the Dutch and
sealed-bid auctions:
b
i
= E(v’|v’ ≤ v
i
)
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
A uniform example
Assume n buyers with reservation prices
independently and uniformly distributed
between L and U.
E(v
max
) = [1/(n+1)]L + [n/(n+1)]U
E(v
2nd
) = [2/(n+1)]L + [(n-1)/(n+1)]U
L
U
E (v
m ax
)
E (v
2nd
)
1
n+ 1
2
n+ 1
n - 1
n + 1
n
n + 1
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
V
max
is n/(n+1) toward U, and
He applies the factor in shading his bid below
his value: (n-1)/n
b
i
= (1/n)*L + [(n-1)/n]* vi
Multiplying: n/(n+1) by (n-1)/n gives:
(n-1)/(n+1) toward U – exactly as in English
auction
L
U
E (v
m ax
)
E (v
2nd
)
1
n+ 1
2
n+ 1
n - 1
n + 1
n
n + 1
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Common-value setting
English auction produces greater revenue, on
average, than the sealed bid auction
Why?
Intuitively:
In common-value settings, buyers must
discount their bids to avoid the winner’s
curse.
The greater the uncertainty (and the number
of bidders) the greater the bid discount.
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Common-value setting
English auction conveys more information
about others bidder’s estimates of value.
Thus English auction informational advantage
translates into revenue advantage for the
seller.
In auction experiments, however, bidder fall
pray to the winner’s curse and sealed-bid
auction holds a slight revenue advantage to
English auction, especially when the item’s
value is highly uncertain and when
competition is high.
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Bidder risk aversion
No effect on bidding in English auction
(bidding up to full value is still dominant
strategy
In sealed-bid auctions this implies higher bids
– smaller but more certain profit.
If a bidder’s value for an item is uncertain,
risk aversion implies reduction in certainty
equivalent value, which in turn lowers bids.
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Value asymmetry
Buyers values are draw from different
distributions
Sealed-bid auction gives higher expected
revenue than English auction
Auctions
Optimal auctions – summary
Experiments confirm the following:
For common-value auctions:
For risk-neutral bidder, the rank order is:
English
> second highest sealed bid > Dutch =
highest price sealed bid
The seller does better with English auctions, whether
risk neutral or not.
Auctions
Optimal auctions – expected auction
revenue
Experiments confirm the following:
For private-value auctions:
For
risk neutral bidders
, English, Dutch, highest
sealed bid, or second highest bid auctions are all
alike in their outcome.
When bidders are
risk-averse,
the rank order from
highest is:
Dutch = highest price sealed bid
> English = second
highest sealed bid
Auctions
Additional readings
http://www.auctusdev.com/auctiontypes.html